
When to Rob a Bank
...and 131 more warped suggestions and well-intended rants.
Categories
Business, Nonfiction, Psychology, Science, Economics, Audiobook, Sociology, Essays, Social Science, Humor
Content Type
Book
Binding
Hardcover
Year
2015
Publisher
William Morrow
Language
English
ASIN
0062385321
ISBN
0062385321
ISBN13
9780062385321
File Download
PDF | EPUB
When to Rob a Bank Plot Summary
Introduction
The day I first encountered economic thinking outside a textbook changed my life forever. I was standing in a long line at a coffee shop, watching people fidget impatiently as a single barista struggled to serve everyone. A stranger beside me casually remarked, "They could easily reduce this line by charging $1 more during rush hour." I was struck by the simplicity and brilliance of the observation. Why hadn't I thought of that? This stranger was seeing invisible forces at work where I only saw frustration. This is the magic of economic thinking - it reveals the hidden patterns governing our everyday choices and behaviors. The authors of this book have mastered the art of uncovering these patterns in the most unexpected places. Through clever data analysis and unconventional questions, they illuminate why drug dealers still live with their mothers, how sumo wrestlers cheat, why real estate agents sell their own homes for more than yours, and how names shape our destinies. Their approach isn't about supply and demand curves or financial markets, but rather about the economics of everyday life - the incentives that drive our decisions, the hidden data that reveals our true motivations, and the surprising connections between seemingly unrelated phenomena. By the end of this journey, you'll never look at the world quite the same way again.
Chapter 1: Incentives: The Hidden Force That Shapes Our Decisions
When Chicago public school teachers faced new standardized tests in the 1990s, something peculiar happened. Student scores suddenly improved dramatically, particularly in certain classrooms. The school board was thrilled, but researchers Steven Levitt and John List were suspicious. They noticed strange patterns in the answer sheets - identical blocks of answers, including identical mistakes, across multiple students. More tellingly, difficult questions at the end of tests were answered correctly while easier questions were missed. The researchers devised an ingenious method to detect cheating. They created an algorithm that identified classrooms where students performed unusually well on difficult questions but struggled with easy ones, where blocks of identical answers appeared, and where performance spiked dramatically but temporarily. When they retested students from suspicious classrooms under controlled conditions, scores plummeted. The evidence was clear: teachers had been changing students' answers after the tests were collected. Why would respected professionals risk their careers this way? The answer lies in incentives. The Chicago school system had implemented high-stakes testing with significant rewards for improved scores and severe penalties for poor performance. Teachers could receive recognition and financial bonuses, while schools with low scores faced potential closure. The system had created powerful incentives that pushed some teachers to cheat rather than teach better. This pattern extends far beyond education. The authors found similar behavior in sumo wrestling tournaments, where wrestlers with critical records mysteriously won matches against higher-ranked opponents who had already secured their advancement. In real estate, agents keep their own homes on the market longer and sell them for higher prices than their clients' homes. In each case, the incentive structure explained the behavior better than individual character. The lesson is profound: humans respond to incentives in predictable ways, often regardless of professional ethics or personal values. When designing systems - whether in education, business, or public policy - we must carefully consider not just the intended consequences but also how people might respond to the incentives we create. The invisible hand of incentives shapes our world in ways both subtle and dramatic, reminding us that economics isn't just about money, but about understanding the hidden forces that drive human behavior.
Chapter 2: Data Revelations: When Numbers Tell Unexpected Stories
In the late 1990s, Romania's orphanages were overflowing with abandoned children. The problem seemed to defy solution until an economist named Cristian Popescu decided to examine the data behind the crisis. What he discovered was surprising: government policies intended to help children were actually causing the problem. Romania provided free housing and care for any abandoned child, but offered almost no support for struggling families trying to keep their children. The incentive structure unintentionally encouraged desperate parents to abandon their children to the state. When Romania redirected just 15% of orphanage funding to family support programs, abandonment rates dropped dramatically within two years. This story illustrates the power of letting data speak for itself, even when it contradicts conventional wisdom. The authors consistently demonstrate this approach throughout their work. When they examined the dramatic drop in U.S. crime rates during the 1990s, they tested every popular explanation: innovative policing strategies, increased incarceration, changes in crack cocaine markets, and demographic shifts. While these factors contributed, their statistical analysis revealed a surprising primary cause: the legalization of abortion two decades earlier had resulted in fewer unwanted children born into adverse circumstances. Similarly, when examining real estate data, they discovered that seemingly innocent phrases in property listings like "motivated seller" or "well maintained" actually correlated with lower sale prices and longer time on market. The data revealed that these terms were code for "desperate to sell" and "no recent updates" - information that savvy buyers could use to their advantage. The authors' approach to swimming pool safety statistics revealed that children are 100 times more likely to die in a swimming pool than from a gun accident, despite media coverage suggesting the opposite. Their analysis of baby names showed how naming patterns cascade through society, starting with wealthy families and trickling down through socioeconomic levels over decades. What makes this data-driven approach so powerful is its ability to cut through rhetoric, assumptions, and conventional wisdom. By following the numbers wherever they lead, we can discover truths that might otherwise remain hidden. The world is full of complex problems with non-obvious solutions, and only by carefully examining what the data actually tells us - rather than what we think it should tell us - can we hope to understand the true nature of these challenges and address them effectively.
Chapter 3: Conventional Wisdom: Why We're Often Wrong
The authors tell a fascinating story about the widespread belief that more police officers on the streets leads to lower crime rates. This seems like common sense - more cops means more criminals caught and more crime deterred. When New York City's crime rate fell dramatically in the 1990s, many attributed this success to increased police presence and aggressive "broken windows" policing. The conventional wisdom seemed confirmed, and cities across America rushed to implement similar strategies. However, when the authors dug into the data, they discovered something unexpected. While more police did correlate with lower crime in some cities, the effect was much smaller than believed. In New York's case, the timing didn't match - crime had already begun falling before the new policing strategies were implemented. Their analysis revealed that factors like the waning crack epidemic, economic growth, changing demographics, and even the legalization of abortion twenty years earlier explained most of the crime reduction. The conventional wisdom had oversimplified a complex phenomenon. This pattern repeats throughout the book. Consider the conventional wisdom that real estate agents always act in their clients' best interests. The data showed that agents selling their own homes kept them on the market an average of ten days longer and sold them for 3% more than comparable client properties. The incentive structure - agents earn only a small fraction of any additional value they secure for clients - explained this discrepancy better than assuming bad character. Similarly, conventional wisdom holds that campaign spending determines election outcomes. Yet when the authors compared candidates who narrowly won elections with those who narrowly lost, they found virtually no correlation between spending and results. What looked like causation was actually reverse causation - candidates expected to win attracted more donations, rather than donations causing wins. Even experts fall prey to conventional wisdom. When the authors surveyed pediatricians about the dangers children face, most ranked gun accidents among the top threats. The data showed that a child is one hundred times more likely to drown in a swimming pool than die from a gun accident. Our perceptions of risk are shaped more by media coverage and dramatic stories than by statistical reality. The lesson here isn't that conventional wisdom is always wrong, but that it should be questioned and tested against data. Human intuition evolved to handle immediate threats and social interactions, not to process complex statistics or identify subtle causal relationships. By learning to recognize when we're relying on conventional wisdom rather than evidence, we can make better decisions and avoid costly mistakes based on what "everyone knows" but few have actually verified.
Chapter 4: Unintended Consequences: The Ripple Effects of Policies
When the city of Albuquerque instituted a $1,000 fine for owners of vehicles involved in drunk driving incidents, they expected to reduce alcohol-related accidents. Instead, they witnessed a disturbing trend: hit-and-run accidents increased by 9 percent. Drivers who had been drinking now had a powerful incentive to flee accident scenes rather than face the steep fine. The policy designed to make roads safer had the unintended consequence of creating a different, equally dangerous problem. This pattern of unintended consequences appears repeatedly in the authors' research. When child safety seat laws were expanded to cover older children, parents dutifully complied, believing they were protecting their children. Yet when the authors analyzed crash data, they found that for children aged 2-6, safety seats were no more effective than regular seat belts at preventing serious injury or death. The unintended consequence? Families with three young children often had to purchase larger, less fuel-efficient vehicles to accommodate three safety seats in the back, increasing pollution and accident risk. Perhaps the most striking example involves wildlife conservation. The Endangered Species Act was designed to protect threatened species by restricting development on their habitats. However, the authors discovered that when landowners learned their property might be designated as critical habitat, they often rushed to develop or clear the land before restrictions could be imposed. In some cases, this "preemptive development" destroyed more habitat than might have been gradually altered under regulated development. Even well-intentioned social programs can backfire. When a city implemented a program offering cash rewards to high school students for improved grades, test scores initially rose. But researchers later found evidence of increased cheating, students choosing easier classes, and teachers inflating grades. Most concerning, some students' intrinsic motivation to learn was replaced by a focus on external rewards. Online rating systems for products and services were intended to provide helpful consumer information, but the authors found that ratings often follow a J-shaped distribution - many five-star reviews, few middle ratings, and a small cluster of one-star reviews. This pattern emerges because people with moderate experiences rarely bother to leave reviews, while those with extremely positive or negative experiences are motivated to share them, creating a distorted picture. These examples highlight a fundamental insight: complex systems rarely respond to interventions in simple, linear ways. When we pull one lever, we often trigger multiple reactions throughout the system. Good intentions don't guarantee good outcomes, and solving one problem frequently creates another. The key to effective policy isn't just identifying a problem and implementing a solution, but carefully considering how people will adapt their behavior in response to new incentives. By anticipating these ripple effects, we can design more robust interventions that achieve their intended goals without creating equally problematic side effects.
Chapter 5: Crime and Economics: Surprising Connections
In the late 1990s, the authors encountered a young graduate student named Sudhir Venkatesh who had embedded himself with a Chicago gang to study their operations. What he discovered was surprising: the gang functioned much like a corporation, with a clear organizational hierarchy, financial record-keeping, and even performance incentives. The gang's detailed ledgers revealed that while the leader earned about $100,000 annually (tax-free), the average foot soldier made just $3.30 per hour - less than minimum wage at McDonald's. Yet these young men faced a 1-in-4 chance of being killed over four years. Why would anyone accept such terrible terms? The answer lay in tournament theory - the same economic principle that explains why thousands of actors work as waiters for years hoping for their big break. The foot soldiers weren't working for their current wage but for the small chance of promotion to the lucrative upper ranks. The gang had created a system where the visible success of a few leaders motivated many others to accept dangerous, low-paying positions. This economic lens reveals surprising patterns across criminal activities. When analyzing data on bank robberies in the UK, the authors found that the average take was about £20,000 per robbery, with a 1-in-5 chance of being caught. After accounting for prison time, the effective hourly "wage" for bank robbery worked out to about £12 per hour - hardly worth the risk. This explains why bank robbery has declined while cybercrime has increased; the risk-reward calculation for digital theft is simply more favorable. The authors also examined the economics of drug dealing, prostitution, and other illegal markets. They found that these underground economies follow many of the same principles as legitimate businesses: supply and demand set prices, competition drives innovation, and participants respond rationally to incentives. When one city cracked down on street-level drug dealing, dealers didn't disappear - they adapted by moving indoors, using technology to arrange sales, and developing more discreet delivery methods. Perhaps most controversially, the authors explored the relationship between abortion legalization in the 1970s and crime reduction in the 1990s. Their data analysis suggested that unwanted children, born into adverse circumstances before Roe v. Wade, were more likely to engage in criminal activity as they reached their high-crime years. When abortion became legal, the number of such births decreased, contributing to lower crime rates two decades later. These economic analyses of crime challenge our intuitions and conventional approaches to law enforcement. They suggest that understanding the incentive structures behind criminal behavior - rather than focusing solely on moral condemnation or punishment - might lead to more effective prevention strategies. By recognizing that criminals respond to costs, benefits, and opportunities just like legitimate market participants, we gain new insights into how to design policies that actually reduce harmful behaviors rather than simply driving them underground or into new forms.
Chapter 6: The Power of Names: How Labels Shape Our Future
In the early 1980s, a California couple named Roland and Landria Fryer welcomed their first child, a son. As African Americans raising a child in a society still marked by racial inequality, they made a conscious decision: they would give their son a distinctively white-sounding name, Roland G. Fryer Jr., hoping it might open doors that might otherwise remain closed. Decades later, their son became an economics professor at Harvard, where he conducted groundbreaking research on racial discrimination - including a study on how names affect opportunity. Professor Fryer and his colleagues analyzed thousands of résumés sent to employers, identical except for one detail: some had traditionally white-sounding names like Emily and Greg, while others had distinctively Black-sounding names like Lakisha and Jamal. The results were striking - résumés with white-sounding names received 50 percent more callbacks than identical résumés with Black-sounding names. This experiment revealed how a single label - a name - could significantly alter a person's economic opportunities. The authors discovered that names carry powerful signals throughout our lives. They analyzed millions of birth records and found that children's names follow distinct socioeconomic patterns. High-income, highly educated parents pioneer unusual but sophisticated names (like Anastasia or Sebastian), which then cascade down the socioeconomic ladder over time. Meanwhile, lower-income families often create innovative new names or unique spellings that later move upward through society. This naming pattern creates a constantly evolving signaling system. A name that indicated high status in one generation might signal something entirely different twenty years later. The name "Madison" began as an elite choice in the 1980s but became one of the most popular girls' names across all demographics by the 2000s. Parents intuitively understand this evolution, which is why trendsetting parents abandon names once they become too common. Beyond socioeconomic signals, the authors found that names can create self-fulfilling prophecies. Boys with traditionally feminine names like Ashley and Shannon were more likely to exhibit behavioral problems in school, particularly after transferring to schools where their peers didn't know them. Girls named after gemstones like Ruby and Amber were statistically more likely to become exotic dancers than girls with more traditional names like Emma or Sarah. Perhaps most surprisingly, the researchers discovered that a person's name can influence their career choice - a phenomenon called "nominative determinism." They found a statistically significant overrepresentation of people named Dennis and Denise among dentists, and Georges among geologists. While these effects are subtle, they suggest that the labels we're given can unconsciously shape our life paths. These findings reveal how powerful labels can be in shaping our identities and opportunities. While we might like to believe that our society judges people purely on their merits, the evidence suggests otherwise. Names - these arbitrary labels assigned at birth - carry information that others use, consciously or unconsciously, to make judgments about us. Understanding this reality doesn't mean we should all choose the same "advantageous" names for our children, but it does highlight how seemingly minor choices can ripple through a lifetime, creating both opportunities and obstacles that might otherwise not exist.
Chapter 7: Risk Perception: Why We Fear the Wrong Things
On a clear September morning in 2001, terrorism transformed from an abstract threat to a visceral fear for most Americans. In the months that followed, millions abandoned air travel in favor of driving - a decision that felt safer but was, statistically speaking, far more dangerous. The authors calculated that the additional road miles traveled in the year after 9/11 resulted in approximately 1,500 excess auto fatalities - more than half the death toll of the attacks themselves. This tragic miscalculation of risk illustrates how our intuitive fear responses often lead us astray. The authors explore numerous examples of this phenomenon. Swimming pools, for instance, cause far more child deaths than guns - a child is one hundred times more likely to die in a residential pool than in a gun accident. Yet many parents who would never keep a gun in their home think nothing of installing a pool, influenced by the dramatic media coverage of rare gun accidents and the relative invisibility of drowning statistics. Similarly, when the authors analyzed what Americans fear most, they found little correlation with actual mortality data. People consistently overestimate the risks of dramatic, visible threats like terrorist attacks, plane crashes, and murder, while underestimating common killers like heart disease, diabetes, and ordinary accidents. The most feared risks share key characteristics: they're novel, catastrophic, beyond personal control, and receive disproportionate media coverage. This misalignment of fear and reality has profound consequences. After shark attacks make headlines, beach attendance drops precipitously, even though the statistical risk remains infinitesimal. Conversely, when familiar risks like texting while driving don't trigger our fear response, we engage in them regularly despite their significant danger. The authors found that people who accurately assessed the risk of texting while driving were no less likely to do it - knowledge alone doesn't overcome our faulty risk perception. The authors also discovered that risk perception varies systematically across populations. Women generally perceive risks as larger and more problematic than men do, while white males tend to see the world as less risky than any other demographic group. These differences persist even among experts with identical information, suggesting deep psychological and cultural influences on risk assessment. Perhaps most concerning, our misaligned fears drive misallocated resources. After 9/11, the United States spent billions on terrorism prevention while underfunding measures to address heart disease, which kills over 600,000 Americans annually. Similarly, parents invest in expensive car seats for children over age two (which data shows provide no additional protection over regular seatbelts) while neglecting proven safety measures like swimming lessons. Understanding these patterns doesn't mean we should ignore dramatic risks or stop taking precautions. Rather, it suggests we should approach risk more analytically, comparing the statistical likelihood of different threats and the effectiveness of various protective measures. By recognizing our tendency to fear the dramatic over the common, the novel over the familiar, and the uncontrollable over the manageable, we can make more rational decisions about both personal safety and public policy, potentially saving many more lives than our instinctive fears would protect.
Summary
Throughout this journey into the hidden side of everything, we've seen how economic thinking illuminates the invisible forces shaping our world. From the power of incentives that drive teachers to cheat and real estate agents to undersell your home, to the surprising data that reveals why drug dealers live with their mothers and how your name might determine your future, the authors have consistently challenged conventional wisdom with evidence. They've shown us that what we think we know is often wrong, that policies frequently create unintended consequences, and that our perception of risk rarely aligns with reality. The true gift of this economic perspective isn't just in understanding these patterns, but in applying them to our own lives. We can design better incentives for ourselves and others by recognizing how they shape behavior. We can question conventional wisdom by seeking data rather than accepting common beliefs. We can anticipate the ripple effects of our choices rather than being surprised by unintended consequences. And perhaps most importantly, we can make better decisions by calibrating our fears to match actual risks rather than dramatic headlines. In a world increasingly driven by emotion and polarization, this evidence-based approach offers something precious: a clearer view of reality and more effective tools for navigating it. The economics of everyday life isn't about money or markets - it's about seeing the hidden patterns that others miss and using that vision to make better choices for ourselves and our communities.
Best Quote
“Our worst critics prefer to stay.” ― Stephen J. Dubner, When to Rob a Bank: ...And 131 More Warped Suggestions and Well-Intended Rants
Review Summary
Strengths: The book's exploration of economic principles applied to unconventional topics captivates readers with its fresh perspectives. Humor and wit effectively engage the audience, making complex ideas accessible and enjoyable. The informal style allows for easy reading in short bursts, while data-driven insights are presented in a fun manner.\nWeaknesses: Some readers feel the collection format lacks cohesion and depth compared to a traditional narrative. For those familiar with the Freakonomics blog or previous works, the content may seem repetitive.\nOverall Sentiment: Reception is mixed, yet generally favorable, especially among Freakonomics fans and those seeking an entertaining read. The book is appreciated for its unique approach to everyday questions through an economic lens.\nKey Takeaway: "When to Rob a Bank" offers a light-hearted yet insightful exploration of human behavior and everyday phenomena, challenging conventional wisdom through engaging economic analysis.
Trending Books
Download PDF & EPUB
To save this Black List summary for later, download the free PDF and EPUB. You can print it out, or read offline at your convenience.

When to Rob a Bank
By Steven D. Levitt