Home/Nonfiction/Edge of Chaos
Loading...
Edge of Chaos cover

Edge of Chaos

Why Democracy is Failing to Deliver Economic Growth – and How to Fix It

3.4 (379 ratings)
23 minutes read | Text | 9 key ideas
As the pulse of global prosperity falters, Dambisa Moyo’s "Edge of Chaos" ignites a bold conversation about the future of liberal democracy. Moyo, a visionary economist, confronts the unsettling truth: our beloved democracies, once thriving growth engines, are now sputtering under the weight of short-sighted policies and rising inequalities. With societies teetering on the brink of nationalism and protectionism, she argues for a profound transformation—a daring reimagining of democratic governance that prioritizes long-term economic vigor. This book is not just a critique; it is a clarion call to action, challenging readers to envision a reinvigorated democratic landscape that secures prosperity and stability for the next century.

Categories

Nonfiction, History, Economics, Politics, Sociology, Social Science, Society, Political Science

Content Type

Book

Binding

Hardcover

Year

2018

Publisher

Basic Books

Language

English

ASIN

0465097464

ISBN

0465097464

ISBN13

9780465097463

File Download

PDF | EPUB

Edge of Chaos Plot Summary

Introduction

In today's world, we face a daunting challenge: liberal democracy appears increasingly incapable of delivering sustained economic growth. While the post-Cold War era initially promised prosperity through democratic capitalism, we now stand at an edge of chaos where expressions of discontent with the established order have intensified, particularly since the 2008 financial crisis. From the Occupy Wall Street protests to anti-austerity marches in Europe and uprisings in the Middle East, citizens worldwide are rebelling against political systems that fail to deliver economic progress. The fundamental issue confronting us is that democracy, in its current form, has become myopic. Short-term electoral incentives encourage politicians to favor policies with immediate benefits rather than addressing long-term structural challenges. This political myopia has exacerbated severe economic headwinds—massive demographic shifts, widening income inequality, technological disruption, natural resource scarcity, and unsustainable debt—that threaten global prosperity. What follows is an examination of how democracy might be reformed to better address these challenges, by implementing mechanisms that extend political time horizons and improve the quality of both policymaking and voter participation. Only through such reforms can we step back from the edge of chaos and restore sustainable economic growth.

Chapter 1: The Imperative of Economic Growth for Human Progress

Economic growth is vital for fulfilling basic human needs and improving lives. When growth wanes, living standards deteriorate, poverty increases, and social instability rises. This connection between economic growth and human welfare can be observed throughout history, from the French Revolution—triggered by economic crisis and food shortages—to modern Greece, where GDP contracted by 45% between 2008 and 2016, leading to social unrest and political upheaval. Growth enhances living standards in three main ways. First, it provides individuals with opportunities to improve their own circumstances through increased income, allowing them to secure better healthcare, education, and housing. Second, it enables individuals to positively impact their wider communities by creating employment opportunities and making investments that benefit others. This multiplier effect occurs as money circulates through an economy, with initial expenditures generating multiple subsequent transactions and broader economic activity. Third, and perhaps most profoundly, growth helps preserve transparent political structures. Economic stress creates conditions for political upheaval and can undermine democratic institutions. Germany in the 1920s and 1930s offers a classic example, where economic collapse enabled the rise of extremism. More recently, Spain's economic contraction after 2008 fueled Catalonian independence movements that threatened national unity. From a technical perspective, economic growth depends on three key factors: capital (investments minus deficits and debts), labor (both quality and quantity), and total factor productivity (including innovation, technology, political systems, and regulations). Productivity accounts for over 50% of why some countries grow while others stagnate. Effective governments with transparent laws, clearly defined property rights, and technological advancement create conditions for higher productivity and thus catalyze economic growth. While growth alone cannot solve every societal problem—it cannot entirely eliminate terrorism or fully resolve income inequality—it remains crucial for addressing most challenges facing humanity. Without economic growth, governments lack resources to fund essential public goods like education, healthcare, and infrastructure. Growth helps reduce poverty, increase opportunities, and create stability that discourages extremism. Despite its limitations, economic growth serves as the foundation for human progress and social advancement.

Chapter 2: The Structural Headwinds Threatening Global Prosperity

Global economic growth faces seven hurricane-strength headwinds that collectively threaten to derail prosperity. The first headwind is the crushing burden of debt. Global debt has grown by $57 trillion since the financial crisis, raising the ratio of debt to GDP by 17 percentage points. While moderate debt can stimulate growth by funding important investments, excessive debt diverts resources from productive uses toward interest payments. In the UK, interest payments on public debt consumed 8% of total tax revenue in 2015—money that could have otherwise funded education or infrastructure. The second headwind is natural resource scarcity. Key inputs for economic growth—arable land, potable water, energy, and minerals—face mounting pressure. Although only 11.3% of China's land is arable, its 1.3 billion people need food, prompting aggressive overseas resource acquisition. Water shortages threaten global stability, with the Office of the Director of National Intelligence warning that "between now and 2040, fresh water availability will not keep up with demand." This scarcity is compounded by rapid population growth, with global population expected to reach 9 billion by 2050. Demographics represent another critical headwind. While population growth initially boosted economies, today's demographic shifts are increasingly problematic. By 2050, one in six people globally will be age sixty-five or older, raising dependency ratios and healthcare costs. Simultaneously, many countries face declining workforce quality due to inadequate education investment. The United States ranks thirtieth among thirty-five OECD members in math skills, while globally 71 million young adults under twenty-five remain unemployed. Technological disruption constitutes the fourth headwind. While innovation historically created more jobs than it destroyed, today's automation threatens employment at unprecedented rates. An Oxford Martin School report estimates 47% of US jobs are at risk from technological change, including 3.4 million trucking positions. This technological revolution benefits owners of capital while leaving labor behind, evidenced by declining labor's share of GDP since the 1980s. Income inequality represents a fifth headwind. According to the OECD, advanced economies have lost 8.5% of GDP over twenty-five years due to worsening inequality. In the United States, the top 1% earns fourteen times the average income of everyone else, up from ten times in 1978. This inequality undermines social cohesion, erodes political equality, and hinders economic growth. The final headwinds include declining productivity and capital misallocation. Global labor productivity growth has fallen to 2.1% in 2014 from pre-crisis levels of 2.6%, with developed economies experiencing the sharpest declines. Meanwhile, investment patterns increasingly favor short-term returns over long-term productive assets, further constraining growth potential. These headwinds are unprecedented in their ferocity and combined impact. Unlike previous economic challenges—such as the 1973 oil spike or the 1930s Depression—today's headwinds cannot be effectively addressed through conventional monetary and fiscal policies. They require fundamental reforms in how political systems approach long-term economic challenges.

Chapter 3: Democratic Myopia: How Short-Termism Undermines Growth

Democracy's greatest weakness lies in its inherent short-termism, which directly undermines economic growth. Politicians facing frequent elections are naturally drawn to policies that produce immediate results rather than addressing long-term structural challenges. This myopia explains why democratic governments consistently postpone difficult decisions about infrastructure, education reform, and pension sustainability, even when the long-term consequences are clearly detrimental. Electoral cycles fundamentally misalign political incentives with economic needs. According to McKinsey Global Institute, the average tenure of a political leader in the G20 plus Nigeria has declined from 6 years in 1946 to 3.7 years today. Meanwhile, the typical business cycle lasts about 69 months (nearly six years). This mismatch means politicians rarely have incentives to implement policies that would deliver growth over a complete economic cycle, instead focusing on quick fixes that will help them win the next election. The problem of short-termism has spread beyond government into the private sector. CEO tenures have shortened from an average of 10 years in 1990 to 4.4 years today, while the average lifespan of an S&P 500 company has dropped from 60 years in 1935 to just 18 years in 2011. Corporate managers increasingly prioritize quarterly earnings over long-term investments, with 74% of executive remuneration tied to outperforming annual stock market benchmarks. This orientation drives companies to return money to shareholders rather than invest in growth-producing assets, evidenced by S&P 500 companies paying out more in buybacks and dividends than their entire retained earnings in five of six quarters leading up to June 2016. The infrastructure crisis illustrates the consequences of this myopia. The American Society of Civil Engineers gave the United States a D+ grade for overall infrastructure, citing 56,007 structurally deficient bridges and estimating that $2 trillion in investment is needed by 2020. Despite historically low interest rates that make infrastructure investment highly affordable, political gridlock has prevented meaningful action. Meanwhile, institutional investors managing approximately $30 trillion seek long-duration assets to match their pension obligations but find few infrastructure projects available for investment. Several factors have intensified democratic short-termism in recent decades. First, economic ideology shifted from government interventionism that prevailed through the 1960s to a smaller-government approach that emerged in the 1980s, reducing appetite for large public infrastructure programs. Second, the twenty-four-hour news cycle and social media have heightened pressure on politicians to react to daily events rather than focus on long-term planning. Third, wealthy individuals and corporations increasingly substitute for government in providing public goods, further weakening the state's capacity to implement coherent long-term policies. This pervasive short-termism prevents democratic governments from effectively addressing the hurricane headwinds threatening economic growth. Instead of making strategic investments in education, infrastructure, and technology that would enhance long-term productivity, politicians concentrate on policies that produce favorable headlines before the next election. Breaking this cycle requires fundamental democratic reforms that better align political incentives with long-term economic needs.

Chapter 4: The False Promise of Protectionism and State Capitalism

As economic anxiety intensifies, many nations are retreating toward protectionism and state capitalism as supposed remedies for growth challenges. This pivot, however, represents a dangerous misdirection that will ultimately worsen rather than solve our economic problems. The protectionist impulse—raising trade barriers, restricting capital flows, and limiting immigration—appears politically expedient but historically leads to diminished growth and increased conflict. Protectionist trade policies have demonstrably harmful effects. The classic example remains the Smoot-Hawley Tariff of the 1930s, which imposed duties on over 3,200 imported products and contributed to the Great Depression by triggering retaliatory measures from trading partners. Recent data shows similar trends emerging: the G20 imposed 644 discriminatory trade measures on other countries in 2015, while global trade growth has fallen below 3% for five consecutive years. These barriers interrupt global supply chains, reduce productivity through decreased competition, and ultimately harm consumers through higher prices. Capital flow restrictions similarly damage growth prospects. Cross-border capital flows among G20 economies have fallen nearly 70% since mid-2007, partly due to tighter regulations following the financial crisis. When countries impose capital controls, as Cyprus did in 2013, they may temporarily stabilize financial systems but simultaneously discourage investment, innovation, and economic expansion. For emerging economies particularly dependent on foreign investment, these restrictions can be devastating. The Institute of International Finance reported that in 2015, more money flowed out of emerging economies than into them for the first time since 1988. Immigration restrictions complete this protectionist trinity. Despite strong evidence that labor mobility enhances economic efficiency by matching workers to opportunities, many countries have tightened borders in response to populist pressures. This trend ignores demographic realities: aging populations in developed nations need younger workers, while developing countries have surplus labor. Instead of creating regulated pathways for mutually beneficial migration, governments increasingly erect barriers that exacerbate demographic imbalances. Meanwhile, state capitalism—exemplified by China's economic model—offers a seductive alternative to democratic capitalism. China's remarkable growth record, lifting over 300 million people from poverty while building impressive infrastructure, has made this approach appealing to many developing nations. Under state capitalism, government directs economic activity through state-owned enterprises and strategic investments, prioritizing growth over political freedoms. However, state capitalism contains fundamental inefficiencies. By disrupting market mechanisms, it leads to resource misallocation, environmental degradation, and corruption. China itself now faces massive debt problems, property bubbles, and pollution that threatens its economic future. Moreover, the model isn't easily transferable—China's export-led strategy depended on Western consumption that cannot be replicated by all developing nations simultaneously. Both protectionism and state capitalism represent false solutions that address symptoms rather than causes. The real challenge lies in reforming democratic systems to overcome short-termism while preserving the proven advantages of market-based economies: innovation, efficiency, and individual freedom. Only by retooling democracy rather than abandoning it can we create sustainable economic growth that benefits the majority rather than privileged elites.

Chapter 5: A Blueprint for Democratic Reform to Enable Long-Term Growth

Democracy requires substantial reform to overcome myopic decision-making and deliver sustainable economic growth. The blueprint for this democratic revitalization consists of ten radical yet essential proposals designed to extend political time horizons, improve the quality of leadership, and enhance voter engagement. While some may find these reforms challenging or even objectionable, they collectively address the fundamental structural flaws undermining democratic capitalism's ability to generate prosperity. The first critical reform involves mechanisms to bind governments more firmly to long-term policies. Currently, democratic systems suffer from time inconsistency—policies enacted by incumbents are routinely unwound by successors, creating uncertainty that deters investment. This problem manifests in three ways: ratification hurdles that derail international agreements, non-compliance with existing commitments, and policy reversals by new administrations. By establishing higher thresholds for policy repeal and strengthening international agreements, democracies can create greater policy stability that encourages long-term economic planning. Second, democracies must implement tighter restrictions on campaign contributions to reduce the disproportionate influence of wealthy donors. In the United States, candidates spent over $6.8 billion on federal elections in 2016, with much of this money coming from wealthy individuals and corporations. This creates perverse incentives for politicians to cater to donor interests rather than pursue policies benefiting the broader economy. Restricting campaign finance would help reorient political priorities toward long-term economic health. Third, officeholders should receive competitive salaries and performance-based compensation linked to economic outcomes. Singapore exemplifies this approach, paying its ministers among the highest salaries globally and awarding bonuses tied to GDP growth. This model attracts talented individuals to public service while creating financial incentives for long-term economic stewardship. Coupling higher compensation with restrictions on post-government employment would further reduce incentives for short-term decision making. Fourth, electoral cycles should be lengthened to better match political timeframes with economic challenges. The typical business cycle lasts approximately six years, yet many democracies hold elections every two to four years. Extending terms to five to seven years would give leaders more breathing room to implement reforms that might initially be unpopular but yield long-term benefits. This adjustment must be accompanied by the fifth reform—term limits—to prevent entrenchment of power while still allowing sufficient time for policy implementation. Sixth, democracies should establish minimum qualifications for officeholders, requiring candidates to demonstrate relevant non-political experience. The growing predominance of career politicians with little real-world experience undermines economic decision-making quality. By ensuring leaders bring diverse professional perspectives to governance, democracies can improve policy outcomes across multiple domains. The seventh reform involves redesigning electoral districts to maximize competitiveness. When politicians occupy safe seats, their incentives to deliver effective policies diminish. Independent commissions should draw district boundaries to create meaningful electoral competition, ensuring representatives remain responsive to constituent needs rather than becoming complacent. The final three reforms focus on voters themselves. Mandatory voting would expand democratic participation beyond the most politically engaged segments of society. Education requirements for voters would ensure electoral decisions reflect informed judgment rather than misinformation or emotional appeals. Finally, a weighted voting system could enhance the influence of well-informed citizens while maintaining universal suffrage. These reforms collectively represent a fundamental recalibration of democratic processes to prioritize long-term economic health over short-term political advantage. While implementing them would require overcoming significant institutional and cultural resistance, the alternative—continuing democratic decline amid economic stagnation—poses an even greater threat to human prosperity.

Chapter 6: Practical Implementation: From Binding Governments to Voter Education

Implementing democratic reforms requires practical mechanisms that can overcome entrenched resistance while delivering tangible improvements to governance. These mechanisms must address both institutional structures and public participation to create a democracy capable of sustained economic growth. For binding governments to long-term commitments, several approaches offer promise. International agreements like those governing trade or environmental policy can establish multi-year frameworks that transcend electoral cycles. The European Union exemplifies this approach—despite occasional breaches of commitments during economic stress, its member states have generally maintained policy continuity across multiple governments. Within national contexts, legislation can include sunset provisions requiring supermajority votes for repeal, raising the threshold for policy reversals and encouraging cross-partisan consensus on major economic initiatives. Campaign finance restrictions can draw inspiration from countries like France, where tight caps on donations and expenditures keep election costs modest. The 2017 French presidential election saw Emmanuel Macron's campaign receive approximately 9 million euros from 35,000 individuals—averaging 257 euros per donor—compared to the hundreds of millions spent in American elections. By reducing politicians' dependency on wealthy contributors, such limits help align political incentives with broader economic interests rather than narrower donor concerns. Extending electoral cycles requires calibrating term lengths to economic realities. According to the National Bureau of Economic Research, business cycles since 1945 have averaged 69 months. Setting political terms to similar durations would better match governance timeframes with economic challenges. Some democracies already approximate this pattern—Brazil's federal senators serve eight-year terms, while US senators serve six years. Complementary term limits prevent the accumulation of excessive power while still allowing sufficient time for policy implementation. Minimum qualifications for officeholders represent a more controversial reform but one with historical precedent. The US Constitution already establishes age requirements for federal offices (25 for representatives, 30 for senators, 35 for president). Expanding qualifications to include relevant professional experience would enhance leadership quality without unduly restricting candidacy. Political parties could initially implement such standards voluntarily, potentially leading to constitutional amendments if proven beneficial. Electoral district design offers a relatively straightforward path to improvement. Independent commissions already redraw boundaries in countries like Australia and Canada, producing more competitive elections than partisan gerrymandering. The Iowa model in the United States, where nonpartisan civil servants redraw districts after each census without regard to political advantage, has created more competitive races and responsive representation. For voter-focused reforms, mandatory voting has proven effective in Australia, Belgium, and several other democracies. In these countries, small fines for non-participation have raised turnout to near 90%, compared to barely 60% in US presidential elections. This broader participation reduces the outsized influence of highly motivated but unrepresentative voter segments. Voter education initiatives face more complex implementation challenges. While formal testing requirements risk echoing historical literacy tests used for disenfranchisement, civic education programs in schools and voluntary voter information systems could significantly improve electoral decision quality. Finland's approach—combining universal suffrage with exceptionally strong civic education—demonstrates how democracies can maintain inclusive participation while enhancing voter knowledge. Weighted voting systems, though most controversial, might begin with limited applications in specialized contexts before broader implementation. Professional associations, cooperatives, and other civil society organizations could experiment with expertise-based voting weights, providing data on effectiveness and potential drawbacks. These practical approaches to democratic reform must be tailored to each nation's specific institutional context and cultural values. However, the fundamental principle remains consistent: aligning political incentives with long-term economic prosperity requires structural changes that extend time horizons and improve decision quality at both leadership and voter levels.

Chapter 7: The Potential Consequences of Inaction

Failing to reform our democratic systems would have profound consequences that extend far beyond politics into the fabric of economic and social life. The trajectory of continued democratic decline amid economic stagnation leads toward a world that is poorer, more divided, and increasingly unstable—a genuine edge of chaos from which recovery becomes progressively more difficult. Without addressing political myopia, the economic headwinds identified earlier will intensify rather than abate. Debt burdens will continue growing unsustainably, demographic challenges will worsen as populations age without adequate preparation, resource scarcity will trigger more conflicts, and technological disruption will further hollow out middle-class employment. These trends will accelerate as short-term political thinking prevents implementation of necessary but initially painful reforms in education, infrastructure, environmental protection, and social safety nets. The economic consequences would be severe. Growth rates in developed economies would likely remain below 2%, insufficient to raise living standards for most citizens. Meanwhile, emerging economies would struggle to achieve the 7% growth needed to double per capita incomes within a generation. With diminished economic prospects, social mobility would further decline, cementing inequality and eroding the promise of meritocracy that underpins democratic legitimacy. Political instability would inevitably follow economic disappointment. We already see signs of this pattern: populist movements gaining ground across Europe and the Americas, authoritarian tendencies strengthening in previously democratic states, and increasing skepticism toward democratic institutions among younger generations. A 2016 survey by the Lowy Institute found that just 42% of Australians aged 18-29 believed democracy was "the most preferable form of government," compared to 65% of those over 30. Similar trends appear in established democracies worldwide. Geopolitical tensions would escalate as economic pressure intensifies competition for resources and influence. An economically weakened West would struggle to maintain the international order established after World War II, creating power vacuums that revisionist states would eagerly fill. The resulting instability would further damage economic growth prospects, creating a negative feedback loop of declining prosperity and increasing conflict. Alternative systems—particularly state capitalism—would gain further appeal as democracies falter. China's model, despite its flaws, would attract more adherents among developing nations seeking paths to prosperity without democratic constraints. This shift would not only diminish political freedoms globally but would likely produce inferior economic outcomes over time, as state capitalism's inherent inefficiencies and corruption vulnerabilities eventually manifest. Perhaps most significantly, inaction would squander the historic opportunity to evolve democratic systems for twenty-first century challenges. Democracy has proven remarkably adaptable throughout history, transforming from direct participation in ancient Athens to representative government in modern nation-states. Today's challenges demand another evolutionary leap—one that preserves democratic principles while extending time horizons and improving decision quality. The path forward requires courage to acknowledge democracy's current limitations without abandoning its core values. Democratic reform represents not a retreat from democratic principles but their advancement and adaptation to contemporary realities. By implementing the reforms outlined previously, we can create political systems capable of addressing long-term challenges while remaining accountable to citizens. The alternative—continuing along our current path—leads toward diminishing prosperity, weakening institutions, and growing instability. At stake is not merely economic growth but the viability of democratic governance itself. We stand genuinely at an edge of chaos, where the decisions we make about reforming our political systems will determine whether we step back toward renewed prosperity or forward into prolonged decline.

Summary

The central insight that emerges from this examination is that political myopia, not economic theory or policy, constitutes the fundamental obstacle to sustainable growth in democratic societies. By systematically reforming democratic processes to extend time horizons and improve decision quality, we can better address the structural headwinds threatening global prosperity. The ten proposals outlined—from binding governments to long-term commitments and extending electoral cycles to implementing voter education and expertise-weighted voting—collectively represent a path toward democratic renewal that preserves core democratic values while enhancing capacity for effective economic governance. This perspective invites us to move beyond traditional debates between left and right economic policies, focusing instead on the institutional frameworks that shape how all policies are formulated and implemented. The most profound economic improvements will come not from specific policy prescriptions but from structural reforms that align political incentives with long-term economic health. For those concerned about declining growth, rising inequality, and diminishing opportunities, democratic reform offers the most promising pathway toward a more prosperous and sustainable future. The alternative—continued democratic erosion amid economic stagnation—leads toward an edge of chaos from which recovery becomes increasingly difficult. The choice between reform and decline grows more urgent with each passing year.

Best Quote

“The world has enjoyed a notably long period marked by relative peace and security. Nevertheless, the forecasts of increasing fragile states, mounting conflicts born of natural resource scarcity, and the rising risk in the incidence of terrorism around the world all point to an increasingly politically volatile world, one that is worsened by economic uncertainty. The Horizon 2025: Creative Destruction in the Aid Industry report cautions that within the next decade more than 80 percent of the world’s population will live in fragile states, susceptible to civil wars that could spill into cross-border conflicts.4 The US National Intelligence Council has published a similarly dire forecast of more clashes in decades to come. While this study focuses largely on the prospect of natural resource conflicts, water especially, it underscores the political vulnerability of many economies. A 2016 report by the Institute for Economics and Peace concludes 2014 was the worst year for terrorism in a decade and a half, with attacks in ninety-three countries resulting in 32,765 people killed; 29,376 people died the year before, making 2013 the second worst year.5” ― Dambisa Moyo, Edge of Chaos: Why Democracy Is Failing to Deliver Economic Growth-and How to Fix It

Review Summary

Strengths: The book provides a helpful overview for readers who are not well-versed in global economic and democratic issues.\nWeaknesses: The analysis is described as superficial, naïve, and unimpressive. The book is criticized for being full of statistics that do not support the assertion that countries are on the "edge of chaos." The author is noted for making leaps from facts to conclusions without sufficient justification, and for failing to recognize the difference between correlation and causation.\nOverall Sentiment: Critical\nKey Takeaway: While Dambisa Moyo's "The Edge of Chaos" aims to provide a comprehensive analysis of the global economy and democracy with solutions, it falls short due to its superficial treatment of complex issues and unsupported conclusions.

About Author

Loading...
Dambisa Moyo Avatar

Dambisa Moyo

Dr. Dambisa Moyo is an international economist who writes on the macroeconomy and global affairs.She is the author of the New York Times Bestsellers "Dead Aid: Why Aid Is Not Working and How There Is a Better Way for Africa", "How The West Was Lost: Fifty Years of Economic Folly And the Stark Choices Ahead" and "Winner Take All: China s Race for Resources and What It Means for the World".Ms. Moyo was named by Time Magazine as one of the “100 Most Influential People in the World”, and was named to the World Economic Forum’s Young Global Leaders Forum. Her work regularly appears in economic and finance-related publications such as the Financial Times, the Economist Magazine and the Wall Street Journal.She completed a doctorate in Economics at Oxford University and holds a Masters degree from Harvard University. She completed an undergraduate degree in Chemistry and an MBA in Finance at the American University in Washington D.C..

Read more

Download PDF & EPUB

To save this Black List summary for later, download the free PDF and EPUB. You can print it out, or read offline at your convenience.

Book Cover

Edge of Chaos

By Dambisa Moyo

0:00/0:00

Build Your Library

Select titles that spark your interest. We'll find bite-sized summaries you'll love.