
How Economics Explains the World
A Short History of Humanity
Categories
Business, Nonfiction, Finance, Science, History, Economics, Politics, Audiobook, Social Science, Society
Content Type
Book
Binding
Kindle Edition
Year
2024
Publisher
Mariner Books
Language
English
ASIN
B0CPWX1N9V
ISBN
0063383802
ISBN13
9780063383807
File Download
PDF | EPUB
How Economics Explains the World Plot Summary
Introduction
In prehistoric times, it would have taken our ancestors nearly 60 hours of foraging for timber to produce as much light as a regular household lightbulb provides in a single hour. Fast forward to Babylonian times, and a worker would have labored for 41 hours to generate the same amount of light using oil lamps. By the late 1700s, the time cost had fallen to about five hours of work to produce an hour of candlelight. Today, less than one second of work earns enough to power a modern lightbulb for an hour. This remarkable 300,000-fold increase in productivity illustrates how economic forces have transformed human existence. The story of light illuminates the journey of human economic development—from prehistoric self-sufficiency to modern specialization, from isolated communities to interconnected global markets. Throughout history, economic forces have shaped pivotal moments: Why did Europe colonize Africa rather than the opposite? What caused the Great Depression? How did property rights fuel China's explosive growth in the 1980s? This book explores how markets evolved from ancient trading posts to digital platforms, how innovations spread across civilizations, and how economic principles help explain everything from imperial conquests to modern inequality. By understanding these economic engines of history, we gain insight into not just what happened in our past, but why it happened—and what might lie ahead.
Chapter 1: From Subsistence to Surplus: Agricultural Revolution and Early Trade
For most of human history, our ancestors lived as hunter-gatherers in small nomadic tribes. Life was brutally difficult, with about 40% of babies dying before their first birthday and life expectancy hovering around 33 years. Violence was commonplace, with up to 15% of people in nomadic societies dying violent deaths. Thomas Hobbes was right when he described early human life as "solitary, poor, nasty, brutish, and short." The agricultural revolution, beginning around 10,000 BCE, marked humanity's first great economic transformation. In northwestern India, the town of Kalibangan provides evidence of one of the world's oldest ploughed fields, with furrows running both north-south and east-west, suggesting the cultivation of multiple crops simultaneously. This wasn't just a technological breakthrough—it was an economic one. Farming allowed communities to build up food surpluses, enabling some people to specialize in crafts, construction, and commerce rather than food production. The Indus Valley civilization, which prospered from 3300 to 1300 BCE, developed grid-pattern cities, sophisticated drainage systems, and extensive trade networks that brought jade from China and lapis lazuli from Afghanistan. The plough was perhaps the most transformative agricultural innovation, increasing productivity five to six times over foraging methods. By breaking up earth and controlling weeds, it fundamentally changed human settlement patterns. However, this technology also altered social dynamics. While digging-stick agriculture was relatively gender-equal, plough farming required significant upper body strength, making it more male-dominated. This technological shift had lasting impacts on gender norms—even today, countries with historical plough use typically show less gender equality than those where plough agriculture was uncommon. Settled agriculture created both opportunities and challenges. The surplus it generated made possible the rise of cities, specialized labor, and eventually civilization itself. Yet it also enabled inequality on an unprecedented scale. While hunter-gatherers owned few possessions, farming created storable wealth that rulers could extract. In many regions, kings and emperors seized agricultural surpluses to fund repressive armies and lavish lifestyles. The Roman Empire, despite its architectural and cultural achievements, maintained its power through brutal military campaigns and widespread slavery. Surprisingly, the first agricultural societies often experienced worse health outcomes than their hunter-gatherer predecessors. Archaeological evidence suggests average heights dropped by about 10 centimeters after the transition to farming, as diets became less diverse and focused on starchy staples. Disease spread more easily in crowded settlements. Yet this transition ultimately laid the groundwork for future innovations that would dramatically improve human wellbeing. By creating food surpluses and enabling specialization, agriculture set humanity on a path toward the modern market economy, with all its complexity, productivity, and potential.
Chapter 2: Industrial Transformation: Technology, Capital and Labor (1750-1900)
The industrial revolution beginning in the mid-18th century represents the most significant economic transformation since the adoption of agriculture. Prior to this period, living standards had remained remarkably stagnant for millennia. In Japan, the average real income was $2.80 per day in the year 1000 CE, and just $2.90 per day in 1700. Most children could expect lives materially identical to their parents. But everything changed with industrialization—life expectancy doubled, real incomes increased fourteen-fold, and average heights increased by about 10 centimeters. This transformation wasn't just a single invention but a series of interlocking revolutions. England's highly productive agriculture meant fewer people were needed to produce food, enabling urbanization. Cities like Manchester and Birmingham became innovation hubs where ideas spread rapidly. James Hargreaves' spinning jenny made thread production 100 times more efficient in a single generation. The iron industry was transformed by coke rather than charcoal, while James Watt's improved steam engine in the 1760s harnessed coal power in revolutionary ways. These technologies would ultimately reshape factories, shipping, and enable train travel, though their full impact took decades to realize. As technology advanced, so did economic thinking. In 1776, as Watt's first profitable steam engine entered the market, Adam Smith published his landmark work, "The Wealth of Nations." Smith described how specialization dramatically increased productivity, using the example of a pin factory where ten specialized workers could produce 4,800 pins daily, while a single worker might struggle to make even one. He also articulated how self-interest in markets could benefit society: "It is not from the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer, or the baker, that we expect our dinner, but from their regard to their own interest." Markets coordinated economic activity more efficiently than command economies. The industrial revolution created unprecedented wealth but distributed it unevenly. Real wages in Britain hardly grew during the first fifty years of industrialization, while factory owners amassed fortunes. Urban workers faced terrible conditions, with higher mortality rates than rural residents due to overcrowding and poor sanitation. The workhouse system, established in Britain in 1834, embodied the harsh attitude toward poverty at the time, assuming the poor were inherently lazy and should only receive assistance in exchange for hard labor. These conditions inspired social critiques from novelists like Charles Dickens and George Eliot. By the 1800s, industrialization had spread across Europe and to North America, fundamentally altering the relationship between labor and capital. Corporations emerged as a dominant economic form, allowing investors to pool risk while limiting liability. In response, workers organized into trade unions, though these were initially illegal in many countries. The technological changes disrupted traditional livelihoods, prompting resistance from skilled workers like the Luddites, who smashed mechanical knitting machines that threatened their jobs. While their specific concerns about technology were misplaced—employment grew by over 10% from 1811 to 1821—they identified a pattern that would repeat throughout industrial history: technological change creates both winners and losers, with benefits and costs unevenly distributed.
Chapter 3: Booms, Busts and Reform: The Emergence of Modern Economics (1900-1945)
The early 20th century witnessed dramatic economic cycles that would give birth to modern macroeconomics. At the turn of the century, economist Alfred Marshall solidified the concept of supply and demand with his "Marshallian Cross" diagrams, showing how market equilibrium emerges from the interaction between buyers and sellers. Meanwhile, innovations like Henry Ford's assembly line dramatically increased productivity. When Ford implemented the moving assembly line in 1913, vehicles came off so quickly that the company decided customers could have a car "painted any color that he wants so long as it is black"—because black paint dried fastest. This period of rapid industrialization came crashing down in 1929. After a decade of prosperity known as the "roaring twenties," the stock market collapsed, leading to the Great Depression. By 1932, the US stock market had fallen 89% from its peak. Unemployment reached 25% in the United States, with similar devastation across the industrialized world. Tent cities sprang up in London's Hyde Park, New York's Central Park, and the Sydney Domain. The economic pain was compounded by policy mistakes, particularly the 1930 Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act, which raised tariffs on over 20,000 imported items. Other countries retaliated with their own tariffs, causing global trade to collapse. The Depression sparked an intellectual revolution in economics, led by British economist John Maynard Keynes. Where classical economists believed markets would self-correct, Keynes argued that economies could become trapped in prolonged slumps. He likened the problem to a bee colony deciding to live thriftily—since one bee's consumption is another's production, the entire colony collapses into misery. Keynes recommended government spending to restart economic activity. This view contrasted with Austrian economist Friedrich von Hayek, who saw recessions as necessary corrections for previous excesses—like the hangover that follows a drinking binge. These economic theories reflected different moral worldviews. Keynes was cosmopolitan, optimistic, and confident that government intervention could improve outcomes. Hayek feared that democratic governments could erode liberty. Their debate would shape economic policy for decades to come, with most modern policymakers adopting a broadly Keynesian approach to combating recessions while acknowledging the importance of market forces for long-term growth. The economic trauma of this period also spurred progressive reforms. Frances Perkins, who had witnessed the tragic Triangle Shirtwaist Factory fire that killed 146 workers in 1911, became the first female Cabinet member when President Franklin Roosevelt appointed her as Secretary of Labor in 1933. She helped design the Social Security Act of 1935, providing direct payments to the elderly and dramatically reducing aged poverty. Meanwhile, economist Joan Robinson published "The Economics of Imperfect Competition" in 1933, challenging the assumption that most markets featured many buyers and sellers. Instead, she highlighted how monopolies and oligopolies were common, and introduced the concept of monopsony—when a buyer has pricing power over suppliers, such as a company town's control over workers' wages. World War II brought economic devastation but also innovations in economic planning and measurement. Statisticians like Simon Kuznets developed national income accounts, making it possible to track economic output systematically. These tools would prove essential for managing post-war economies and avoiding another Depression. By 1944, with victory in sight, representatives from 44 Allied nations gathered at Bretton Woods, New Hampshire, to design a new international economic architecture. The resulting agreement created the World Bank and International Monetary Fund, institutions designed to promote stability and prevent the economic nationalism that had contributed to war.
Chapter 4: The Golden Age and Its Limits: Post-War Prosperity (1945-1980)
The three decades following World War II saw unprecedented economic growth across much of the industrialized world. So remarkable was this period that the French called it "les Trente Glorieuses" (the Glorious Thirty), Italians referred to "il boom economico," and Germans celebrated "das Wunder am Rhein" (the Miracle on the Rhine). Real incomes rose dramatically, with the benefits widely shared. In many countries, the gap between rich and poor narrowed as wages rose faster on the factory floor than in the corner office. Home ownership expanded dramatically—in Britain, the share of owner-occupied housing rose from 23% at the end of World War I to nearly 58% by the late 1970s. Several factors contributed to this golden age. The Bretton Woods system established stable exchange rates and promoted trade. The Marshall Plan provided billions in aid to rebuild Western Europe. Strong labor unions, comprising about one-third of employees in advanced economies by the 1970s, helped ensure workers received a fair share of productivity gains. Progressive taxation redistributed wealth, with top marginal rates exceeding 90% in some countries—prompting the Beatles to complain in their song "Taxman" about the government taking "nineteen for me" and leaving just "one for you." Education expanded rapidly, with school completion rates rising and tertiary education becoming increasingly common. Technological innovations transformed daily life. The spread of electricity, refrigerators, automobiles, and television created new consumption possibilities. Air conditioning allowed mass migration toward the equator in many countries—Americans moved to Florida, Australians to Queensland, while cities like Singapore and Dubai boomed. The standardized shipping container, invented by Malcolm McLean in 1956, revolutionized global trade by dramatically reducing transport costs. By the 1970s, many Europeans were getting cars for the first time, while Americans purchased their first freezers. However, prosperity wasn't universal. In China, Mao Zedong's disastrous policies led to catastrophe. The "Great Leap Forward" of 1958 forced farmers to produce iron and steel in backyard furnaces while abandoning agricultural work. Simultaneously, a campaign to eliminate sparrows (which ate grain) backfired when insect populations exploded without their natural predators. The resulting famine killed tens of millions. Later, the Cultural Revolution (1966-1976) attacked intellectuals and sent millions of urban youth to the countryside, disrupting education and economic development. While Hong Kong's economy grew rapidly, mainland China stagnated under communism. Similar problems plagued other communist economies. The Soviet Union produced impressive industrial statistics but failed to deliver consumer goods or address widespread poverty. In Cuba, Fidel Castro's 1959 revolution replaced one form of economic control with another. Even non-communist developing nations struggled. India adopted a heavily regulated "license raj" that required up to 80 agencies to approve new businesses. Economist Raúl Prebisch advocated "import substitution industrialization" across Latin America, encouraging countries to build domestic industries behind high tariff walls rather than engage with global markets. These policies generally failed to deliver sustainable growth. By the late 1970s, the post-war consensus was fraying. Oil price shocks created "stagflation"—a combination of high inflation and economic stagnation that Keynesian policies struggled to address. The collapse of the Bretton Woods system in the early 1970s led to volatile exchange rates. These challenges would soon prompt a fundamental rethinking of economic policy, setting the stage for the market-oriented reforms of the 1980s and beyond.
Chapter 5: Market Revolution: Globalization, Technology and Inequality (1980-2010)
In 1978, in the tiny Chinese village of Xiaogang, eighteen farmers secretly signed a contract that could have cost them their lives. Under communist collectivization, all worked the commune's land but received the same share regardless of effort. Their radical agreement divided the land among families, allowing each to keep any surplus production. The results were dramatic—their harvest that year exceeded the previous five years combined. Initially investigated by authorities, they were spared when China's new leader Deng Xiaoping embraced their approach. This local experiment became the model for national reforms that would lift hundreds of millions of Chinese out of poverty in the coming decades. Around the same time, the United Kingdom and United States embarked on their own market revolutions. Margaret Thatcher, elected in 1979, and Ronald Reagan, elected in 1980, championed policies that reduced government intervention in the economy. Thatcher privatized state-owned enterprises, cut taxes, and confronted union power. Reagan similarly reduced top tax rates from 70% to 28% and deregulated multiple sectors. Both leaders were influenced by economists like Milton Friedman, who advocated free markets and monetary discipline. The approach spread globally—from New Zealand to Mexico, countries embraced privatization, deregulation, and free trade. International trade grew dramatically during this period. The completion of the Uruguay Round of trade talks in 1994 led to the creation of the World Trade Organization, building on decades of tariff reductions that had lowered the average worldwide tariff from 22% in 1947 to just 3%. China joined the WTO in 2001, accelerating its integration into global supply chains. "Tiger" economies like South Korea, Taiwan, Hong Kong, and Singapore, followed by "tiger cubs" including Thailand, Malaysia, and Vietnam, pursued export-led growth strategies that transformed them from poor to middle-income countries within a generation. Technological innovation accelerated with the advent of personal computers, the internet, and mobile communications. The number of worldwide internet users doubled annually in the late 1990s, creating a "Web 1.0" boom followed by the "tech wreck" of 2000 when many early internet companies collapsed. Companies like Google and Amazon emerged from this shakeout to become dominant global firms. In 2002, psychologist Daniel Kahneman received the Nobel Prize in Economics for his work on behavioral economics, showing how human decision-making systematically deviates from the rational model. His research revealed how people use two "systems" of thinking—a fast, intuitive System One prone to biases, and a slower, more analytical System Two. While these decades saw remarkable wealth creation, they also witnessed growing inequality in many countries. The income share of the top 1% increased dramatically in the United States, United Kingdom, and elsewhere. Economist Thomas Piketty's research suggested this was partly because the rate of return on capital typically exceeds the rate of economic growth, causing wealth to concentrate among those who already possess assets. The so-called "elephant curve" of global income growth between 1980 and 2016 showed strong gains for the emerging global middle class (primarily in China and India) and spectacular growth for the global elite, but stagnation for the working and middle classes in advanced economies. Environmental concerns also moved to the forefront of economic thinking. Nicholas Stern's influential 2006 review on climate change described it as "the biggest market failure the world has ever seen," with carbon emissions imposing massive social costs not reflected in market prices. Stern argued that spending roughly 1% of global income could substantially reduce emissions and prevent damage equivalent to losing 5-20% of global income forever. This analysis helped shift climate policy from a purely environmental issue to an economic one, laying groundwork for carbon pricing and other market-based approaches to reducing emissions.
Chapter 6: Crisis and Adaptation: Economic Challenges of the 21st Century
The early 21st century began with economic optimism after recovering from the relatively brief tech bubble burst, but soon faced its greatest financial crisis since the Great Depression. By 2005, housing prices in many countries had soared to unprecedented levels, with lending standards deteriorating simultaneously. In Bakersfield, California, a strawberry picker earning $14,000 annually with no English skills was approved for a $720,000 home mortgage. These "NINJA loans" (no income, no job, no assets) were bundled into securities and sold to investors worldwide, spreading risk throughout the financial system. When the housing bubble burst in 2007-2008, it triggered a global financial meltdown. Average US home values dropped by around one-fifth, with one in ten mortgage holders owing more than their homes were worth. Major financial institutions like Lehman Brothers collapsed, while others required massive government bailouts. The crisis exposed fundamental flaws in financial regulation and risk management. Economist Mark Carney later observed, "Just as there are no atheists in foxholes, there are no libertarians in financial crises." Governments worldwide implemented coordinated fiscal stimulus through the G20, while central banks slashed interest rates to near zero and implemented "quantitative easing"—purchasing financial assets to support the economy. The crisis had lasting consequences, particularly for disadvantaged groups. In the US, Black unemployment remained above 10% for more than six years, while white unemployment never reached double digits. Recovery was slow and uneven, with central banks struggling to stimulate growth despite unprecedented monetary accommodation. By the late 2010s, interest rates had reached historic lows, leading Bank of England economist Andy Haldane to conclude they had never been this low in 5,000 years of economic history. The phenomenon of "secular stagnation"—persistently low growth, inflation, and interest rates—challenged conventional economic thinking. Meanwhile, technology continued transforming economies in unexpected ways. The rise of digital platforms created new markets and disrupted existing ones. Five firms collectively known as "MAMAA" (Meta, Apple, Microsoft, Alphabet, and Amazon) came to dominate Western digital markets, while China's "BATX" (Baidu, Alibaba, Tencent, and Xiaomi) controlled their domestic counterparts. Economists increasingly questioned whether market concentration hurt both consumers and workers. Around one-fifth of US workers had contract clauses limiting their ability to take jobs with competitors, while tech giants were found colluding to suppress wages for software engineers. The COVID-19 pandemic in 2020 delivered another economic shock, causing the worst downturn since the Great Depression. Global income in the second quarter of 2020 fell by 5%, with around 400 million jobs lost worldwide. Governments provided more than $10 trillion in support to affected households and businesses, causing global government debt to jump from ten months to a full year of worldwide income. As lockdowns lifted, pent-up consumer spending combined with supply chain disruptions and Russia's invasion of Ukraine sparked inflation reminiscent of the 1970s. Central banks responded with rapid interest rate increases, ending a decade of ultra-low rates. Throughout these crises, economics itself evolved. Big data transformed research methods, with economists analyzing everything from satellite imagery to social media posts. Harvard's Raj Chetty used tax data on almost the entire US population to study economic mobility, showing that for children born in the 1940s, nearly 90% could expect to earn more than their parents, but for those born in the 1980s, only half would achieve this milestone. His research also revealed how neighborhoods profoundly affect children's outcomes and how friendship networks remain strongly class-based. These new approaches combined with behavioral insights and randomized controlled trials are making economics more empirical, more nuanced, and potentially more useful for addressing the complex challenges of the 21st century.
Summary
Throughout human history, markets have been powerful engines of transformation, reshaping societies from subsistence to abundance. From the agricultural revolution that first created food surpluses to the industrial technologies that multiplied productivity, economic forces have driven human progress. The market system—with its price signals, incentives, and voluntary exchange—has proven remarkably effective at coordinating complex activities across billions of people. Yet markets alone are insufficient. The recurring boom-and-bust cycles of capitalism, the persistence of inequality, and the catastrophic market failure of climate change all demonstrate that unchecked markets can create as many problems as they solve. The greatest economic achievements have come when societies balance market dynamism with thoughtful regulation and social protections. Successful economies maintain competitive markets while preventing monopoly power, embrace international trade while supporting displaced workers, and harness technological innovation while addressing its unequal impacts. Looking forward, humanity faces unprecedented challenges—from artificial intelligence that may transform work to climate change that threatens prosperity itself. Economic thinking will be essential to navigating these waters, helping us design institutions that can deliver sustainable, broadly shared prosperity. The history of economics teaches us that human ingenuity, properly channeled through well-structured markets and guided by democratic choices, can continue to expand human capabilities and wellbeing—if we learn the right lessons from our economic past.
Best Quote
Review Summary
Strengths: The review highlights the book's clarity, insightfulness, and remarkable nature. It praises the book for successfully narrating the emergence of capitalism and the market system, discussing key economic ideas and figures, and outlining the impact of economic forces on world history. The book is described as short, easy to read, and rich in scholarship, with economic concepts seamlessly integrated into the narrative. It is noted for its enthusiasm about economic progress and the role of economics and government in addressing market failures. Weaknesses: Not explicitly mentioned. Overall Sentiment: Enthusiastic Key Takeaway: Andrew Leigh's book is a compelling, accessible introduction to economic history and concepts, appreciated for its clarity and insightful connections between topics, making it beneficial for both economists and non-specialists.
Trending Books
Download PDF & EPUB
To save this Black List summary for later, download the free PDF and EPUB. You can print it out, or read offline at your convenience.

How Economics Explains the World
By Andrew Leigh