
The AI Economy
Work, Wealth and Welfare in the Robot Age
Categories
Business, Nonfiction, Finance, Economics, Politics, Technology, Artificial Intelligence
Content Type
Book
Binding
Hardcover
Year
2019
Publisher
Nicholas Brealey
Language
English
ASIN
147369616X
ISBN
147369616X
ISBN13
9781473696167
File Download
PDF | EPUB
The AI Economy Plot Summary
Introduction
In 1779, as the first steam-powered textile mills began operating in England, few could have imagined how profoundly this technology would transform human civilization. For thousands of years prior, economic progress had been virtually nonexistent - the average person in 1700 lived little better than their counterpart in ancient Rome. Then suddenly, within just a few generations, everything changed. This pattern of technological revolution followed by economic and social transformation has repeated throughout modern history, from steam power to electricity to computers. Each wave brought both tremendous opportunity and wrenching disruption, ultimately delivering unprecedented prosperity while fundamentally reshaping society. The AI revolution represents the latest chapter in this ongoing story, but with unique characteristics that may distinguish it from previous technological transformations. Unlike earlier technologies that primarily extended human physical capabilities, AI directly competes with and complements human cognitive abilities. This raises profound questions about the future of work, income distribution, and even what it means to be human. By examining historical patterns of technological change and their economic consequences, we can better understand the likely trajectory of AI's impact and the policy choices that will determine whether its benefits are broadly shared or narrowly concentrated. This historical perspective offers valuable insights for anyone seeking to navigate the opportunities and challenges of our rapidly evolving technological landscape.
Chapter 1: Industrial Foundations: The First Wave of Automation (1750-1900)
The Industrial Revolution emerged in late 18th century Britain, marking humanity's escape from millennia of economic stagnation. Prior to this transformation, living standards had barely improved for thousands of years - economic historians estimate that per capita GDP doubled only once over a span of 1,800 years before 1800. Most people lived in conditions of subsistence, with life expectancy rarely exceeding 40 years. The revolution began with innovations in textile production, iron making, and steam power, but quickly spread to transform transportation, communication, and eventually every aspect of economic life. The social impact was profound and initially quite painful for many. As production shifted from homes and small workshops to factories, traditional craft workers found their skills devalued. The Luddites, textile workers who destroyed machinery they saw as threatening their livelihoods, exemplify the resistance this transformation provoked. Friedrich Engels documented how early industrialization actually reduced living standards for many workers, creating overcrowded slums and dangerous working conditions in what economic historians now call "the Engels pause" - a period of several decades when productivity rose but wages stagnated or fell. This concentration of benefits among factory owners while workers suffered created intense social tensions and political conflicts. The transformation of work itself represented perhaps the most fundamental change. Adam Smith, while celebrating the efficiency gains from the division of labor, acknowledged its human cost, noting that a worker performing repetitive tasks "has no occasion to exert his understanding." Karl Marx went further, arguing that industrial workers became mere "appendages of machines." The factory system imposed new disciplines of time and supervision that dramatically altered how people experienced their daily lives. The natural rhythms that had governed agricultural work gave way to the relentless precision of the factory whistle and clock. Despite these challenges, the Industrial Revolution ultimately delivered unprecedented improvements in living standards. By 1900, per capita GDP in industrialized nations was nearly three and a half times higher than in 1800. Life expectancy began its steady climb, literacy spread, and material comforts previously available only to the wealthy became accessible to ordinary people. This pattern of disruption followed by broadly shared benefits established a template for subsequent technological revolutions. The key mechanism was what economist Joseph Schumpeter later called "creative destruction" - the process by which new technologies and methods rendered old skills obsolete while creating entirely new opportunities. The lessons of this first wave of automation remain relevant today. Technological revolutions create both winners and losers in the short term, with benefits often concentrated before they diffuse more widely. The transition period can involve significant hardship and social tension. Yet with appropriate institutional adaptations - including new educational systems, labor protections, and eventually social safety nets - societies can harness technological change to dramatically improve living standards. The question now is whether the AI revolution will follow this established pattern or break from it in fundamental ways that require new approaches to ensuring its benefits are broadly shared.
Chapter 2: From Scarcity to Abundance: Productivity's Historical Arc
Throughout most of human history, scarcity defined economic existence. From ancient civilizations through medieval times, productivity growth was virtually nonexistent, with technological innovation occurring at a glacial pace. The typical person in 1700 lived little better than their counterpart in ancient Rome, with most of humanity engaged in subsistence agriculture using methods that had changed little for centuries. This profound stagnation makes what followed all the more remarkable - what economic historians call "the hockey stick of human prosperity," where centuries of flat living standards suddenly curve sharply upward beginning around 1800. The post-World War II period from 1950-1973 represents the pinnacle of this productivity revolution. Often called the "Golden Age" of economic growth, this era saw world GDP grow by an astonishing 4.8% annually, with per capita growth of 2.8%. In West Germany, per capita GDP grew at 5.6% annually, producing a 250% increase in living standards over just 23 years. This extraordinary period combined several growth drivers: postwar reconstruction, technological advances from the 1930s and 1940s, high employment, substantial investment, and expanding international trade. For the first time in history, prosperity was broadly shared across social classes in developed economies, creating a large middle class with unprecedented access to education, healthcare, and consumer goods. However, productivity growth has not followed a smooth upward trajectory. After the Golden Age, growth fell sharply across almost all countries. The oil price shocks of the 1970s, the breakdown of the international monetary system, and subsequent inflation-fighting policies all contributed to this slowdown. More recently, measured productivity growth has been particularly disappointing. In the decade following the 2007-2009 Global Financial Crisis, productivity growth in most developed economies has been notably weak, leading some economists to speak of "secular stagnation" - a persistent condition of low growth despite low interest rates. This recent slowdown has sparked intense debate among economists. Robert Gordon argues that we should view the Industrial Revolution as a one-off event, with technological progress now largely exhausted. He divides industrial progress into three revolutions: the first (1750-1830) centered on steam power and early railroads; the second (1870-1900) on electricity and the internal combustion engine; and the third (from 1960) on computers and digital technology. Gordon contends that the third revolution has delivered less significant productivity improvements than its predecessors, suggesting future growth will be modest at best. Others challenge this pessimistic view, arguing that productivity statistics fail to capture the full value of digital innovations. A study led by Sir Charles Bean concluded that correcting for under-recording of the digital economy could add between 0.35% and 0.65% annually to GDP growth. More importantly, we may be on the cusp of a fourth industrial revolution centered on artificial intelligence, robotics, biotechnology, and nanotechnology. Unlike the digital revolution, which primarily affected information processing and communication, these technologies promise to directly replace human labor across a broad range of activities, potentially delivering dramatic productivity improvements across the entire economy. The historical pattern suggests that technological revolutions deliver their greatest benefits when they coincide with complementary commercial, organizational, and social innovations. The full productivity benefits of electricity weren't realized until factories were redesigned around distributed power rather than central steam engines - a process that took decades. Similarly, the AI revolution may require significant organizational and institutional changes before its full productivity potential is realized. The question is whether we can accelerate this adaptation process while ensuring the benefits are broadly shared rather than narrowly concentrated.
Chapter 3: Creative Destruction: Technology's Impact on Employment Since 1800
The relationship between technological progress and employment has been complex and often counterintuitive since the Industrial Revolution began. In 1821, the economist David Ricardo warned that "the substitution of machinery for human labour is often very injurious to the interests of the class of labourers." This concern has been echoed repeatedly over the past two centuries, yet mass technological unemployment has never materialized. Instead, economies have consistently generated new jobs to replace those eliminated by automation, though often after difficult transition periods and with significant changes in the nature and distribution of work. Agriculture provides the most dramatic example of technology's impact on employment. In 1900, agriculture accounted for 40% of US employment; today it represents just 2%. In the UK, agricultural employment fell from 9% to 1% over the same period. Similar transformations occurred in manufacturing, which once employed nearly 40% of UK workers but now accounts for only 8%. Yet despite these massive sectoral shifts, overall employment has consistently risen, and the employment-to-population ratio has generally increased over time. The jobs lost in agriculture and traditional manufacturing were more than offset by new positions in services, information technology, healthcare, education, and entirely new industries that could not have been imagined beforehand. This pattern of job destruction and creation reflects what economist Joseph Schumpeter called "creative destruction" - the process by which innovation simultaneously eliminates existing economic structures while creating new ones. When assembly line production reduced the labor needed to build automobiles, it simultaneously made cars affordable for millions, creating demand for new roads, service stations, and an entire ecosystem of related businesses. Similarly, while automated switchboards eliminated telephone operators, the digital revolution created millions of jobs in information technology, software development, and related fields. Throughout this process, rising productivity has been the fundamental driver of job creation, as it enables higher wages and increased consumer spending that generates demand for new goods and services. The transition has never been painless, however. Throughout the 19th and 20th centuries, technological change caused immense suffering for individuals and communities whose skills became obsolete. The Luddites who smashed textile machinery were responding to a genuine threat to their livelihoods. More recently, deindustrialization devastated manufacturing communities across Europe and North America in the late 20th century. Many older workers never found comparable employment, and some regions have still not fully recovered decades later. What made these transitions manageable at the societal level was that workers could generally adapt by learning new skills or moving to areas with better opportunities. The pace of change, while disruptive, allowed for generational adaptation. A crucial factor in this process was that technological progress increased overall productivity, raising average wages and living standards. Since 1750, despite occasional reversals, the share of wages and salaries in national income has remained broadly constant in developed economies. This means the benefits of productivity growth were shared relatively equally between workers and capital owners, allowing the majority to benefit from technological progress despite the disruption it caused. When this balance has been disrupted - as during the early Industrial Revolution or in recent decades with rising inequality - social and political tensions have intensified, often leading to institutional reforms that restore a more equitable distribution of technology's benefits. The historical record thus presents a nuanced picture: technological revolutions have consistently created more jobs than they destroyed and raised average living standards substantially, but they have also produced significant hardship for those caught in the transition. The key question is whether the AI revolution will follow this established pattern or represent a fundamental break from the past. If AI can perform not just routine physical tasks but also many cognitive functions, will the economy still generate enough new jobs? And will these jobs be accessible to displaced workers, or will they require skills that many cannot readily acquire? These questions make understanding the specific characteristics of the AI revolution particularly important.
Chapter 4: Digital Disruption: Lessons from the Computer Revolution
The digital revolution that began in the late 20th century offers crucial insights for understanding AI's potential economic impact. Starting with mainframe computers in the 1960s, accelerating with personal computers in the 1980s, and transforming nearly every aspect of life with the internet and smartphones since the 1990s, this revolution represents our most recent experience with transformative technology. Its economic effects have been profound but often surprising, challenging conventional wisdom and revealing the complex ways technology reshapes rather than simply eliminates human work. Initially, the productivity benefits of computerization were surprisingly difficult to detect. As Nobel laureate Robert Solow famously remarked in 1987, "You can see the computer age everywhere but in the productivity statistics." This "productivity paradox" persisted through the early 1990s before a significant productivity acceleration finally emerged in the late 1990s and early 2000s. This delay between technological adoption and productivity growth illustrates an important pattern: transformative technologies often require complementary innovations and organizational changes before their full economic benefits materialize. Companies needed to fundamentally rethink their processes rather than simply computerizing existing workflows - a lesson that applies equally to AI adoption today. The employment effects of the digital revolution have been highly uneven across skill levels and occupations. Routine cognitive tasks like bookkeeping, data entry, and basic customer service have been heavily automated, while both high-skilled analytical jobs and low-skilled service jobs have expanded. This "job polarization" has contributed to wage inequality in many developed economies, with middle-skill jobs declining relative to both high-paid professional positions and lower-paid service work. The workers who have benefited most are those whose skills complement rather than compete with digital technology - what economists call "racing with machines" rather than "racing against machines." Perhaps most significantly, the digital revolution has changed how we should think about economic measurement. Traditional GDP statistics struggle to capture the value of free digital services, quality improvements in digital products, and the consumer surplus generated by innovations like smartphones and internet search. Studies suggest that conventional measures may significantly understate recent improvements in living standards. As Sir Charles Bean's research indicates, correcting for the under-recording of the digital economy could add between 0.35% and 0.65% annually to measured GDP growth - a substantial adjustment that suggests the digital economy's benefits may be greater than commonly recognized. The digital revolution also demonstrates how technology can transform industry structure and market dynamics. Digital platforms like Amazon, Google, and Facebook exhibit powerful network effects and economies of scale that have led to market concentration in many sectors. These "superstar firms" capture an increasing share of profits while employing relatively few workers compared to industrial giants of the past. This has contributed to the declining labor share of national income in many countries - a reversal of the historical pattern where productivity gains were shared relatively equally between labor and capital. Understanding these structural changes is essential for developing appropriate policy responses to the AI revolution. The lessons from the digital revolution suggest that AI's economic impact will be complex and multifaceted rather than simply eliminating jobs. The most profound effects will likely come not from direct automation of existing tasks but from the entirely new products, services, and business models that emerge as the technology matures. The greatest economic benefits will accrue to those who can reimagine processes and organizations to fully leverage AI's capabilities rather than merely applying it to existing workflows. And ensuring these benefits are broadly shared will require deliberate policy choices rather than simply trusting market forces to distribute them equitably.
Chapter 5: AI Economy: Labor Markets and Distribution Challenges
The emerging AI economy presents unprecedented challenges for labor markets and income distribution. Unlike previous technological revolutions that primarily automated physical tasks, AI threatens to automate a wide range of cognitive tasks previously thought to be uniquely human. This fundamental difference has sparked intense debate about whether historical patterns of job creation and destruction will continue or whether we face a future of widespread technological unemployment and increasing inequality. AI's potential impact on employment is extraordinarily broad. McKinsey estimates that by 2030, between 375 million and 700 million workers globally could be displaced by automation, depending on the pace of technological adoption. An Oxford University study concluded that 47% of US jobs are at high risk of automation. However, these headline figures can be misleading. McKinsey also notes that fewer than 5% of occupations are entirely automatable with current technology, though about 60% of occupations could have 30% or more of their constituent activities automated. This suggests a future where most jobs are transformed rather than eliminated entirely, with humans working alongside increasingly capable machines. The most vulnerable jobs are those involving predictable, routine tasks in structured environments - regardless of whether they are physical or cognitive. Bank tellers, retail cashiers, data entry clerks, and basic accounting functions face high automation risk. Middle-skill, middle-income jobs appear particularly vulnerable, potentially accelerating the "hollowing out" of labor markets observed during the digital revolution. This could further exacerbate income inequality, as displaced workers compete for remaining jobs at the lower end of the wage spectrum while those with the skills to complement AI technologies see their productivity and earnings rise. The geographic distribution of AI's benefits and costs also presents challenges. Regions with strong technology sectors and highly educated workforces are likely to benefit disproportionately, while areas dependent on routine manufacturing or administrative work could face significant disruption. This could exacerbate existing regional inequalities within countries and potentially widen gaps between technologically advanced and developing nations. The traditional development pathway of export-oriented manufacturing based on low labor costs may narrow as AI and robotics reduce the importance of labor costs in production decisions, potentially closing off this route to prosperity for today's developing economies. The income distribution effects of AI adoption depend critically on whether the technology primarily substitutes for human labor or complements it. If AI mainly substitutes for labor, the share of national income going to capital owners could rise substantially, potentially increasing inequality. If AI primarily complements human abilities, enhancing worker productivity across many occupations, the benefits might be more widely shared. The actual outcome will likely vary significantly across different sectors and job categories, but the overall trend toward greater capital intensity in production suggests distributional challenges ahead. These labor market and distributional challenges demand thoughtful policy responses. The historical record suggests that technological revolutions eventually create more prosperity than they destroy, but the transition period can involve significant hardship for displaced workers and communities. The pace of AI adoption may exceed the natural rate of workforce adaptation through retirement and education, requiring more active policy intervention than previous technological transitions. Ensuring that AI's benefits are broadly shared will require reimagining education, strengthening social safety nets, and potentially developing new mechanisms to distribute the productivity gains from increasingly automated production.
Chapter 6: Policy Imperatives: Navigating the Robot Age
As artificial intelligence transforms the economy, policymakers face complex tradeoffs between encouraging innovation and ensuring that the benefits are broadly shared. The historical record suggests that technological revolutions eventually raise living standards across society, but the transition period can involve significant disruption and inequality. Effective economic policy in the AI era must balance multiple objectives: promoting technological progress, facilitating workforce adaptation, and maintaining social cohesion. Education policy represents perhaps the most critical area for intervention. Traditional education systems designed for the industrial era emphasize standardized knowledge acquisition and routine cognitive skills - precisely the areas where AI excels. Future education must instead focus on developing distinctively human capabilities that complement rather than compete with AI. This includes creativity, emotional intelligence, complex problem-solving, and adaptability. As investor Mark Cuban observed, as automation becomes the norm, it will be "free thinkers who excel in liberal arts" who are most in demand. Education must also become more flexible and continuous, supporting multiple career transitions throughout life rather than front-loading education in youth. Labor market policies will need significant recalibration. The traditional safety net designed around temporary unemployment may prove inadequate in an era where entire occupational categories face obsolescence. More robust income support, retraining programs, and relocation assistance may be necessary to help displaced workers transition to new roles. Some economists have proposed more radical solutions like universal basic income to ensure economic security amid rapid technological change, though such approaches raise complex questions about work incentives, fiscal sustainability, and social values. Others suggest expanding public employment in areas where human touch remains essential, like education, healthcare, and elder care. The distribution of AI's economic benefits will depend significantly on market structure and competition policy. The economics of AI - with its reliance on massive datasets, network effects, and increasing returns to scale - naturally tends toward market concentration. Without effective competition policy, the productivity gains from AI could accrue primarily to a small number of dominant firms and their shareholders rather than being passed on to consumers through lower prices or to workers through higher wages. Updating antitrust frameworks for the AI era represents a crucial policy challenge, potentially requiring new approaches to defining market power in the digital age. Tax policy will also require substantial rethinking. The current tax system in most countries places a higher burden on labor income than on capital income, potentially exacerbating inequality as AI shifts the balance of economic returns from workers to capital owners. Some have proposed a "robot tax" to slow automation and generate revenue for worker assistance programs, though such approaches risk impeding beneficial productivity growth. More promising approaches might include more progressive taxation of capital income, broader wealth taxes, or expanded earned income tax credits to supplement wages in low-productivity sectors. International coordination on AI policy presents another critical frontier. Countries that attempt to block or heavily restrict AI adoption risk falling behind in global competitiveness, while those that pursue technological advancement without addressing its distributional consequences risk social and political instability. Finding mechanisms for international cooperation on AI governance while respecting different cultural and political approaches represents a critical diplomatic challenge for the coming decades. This includes developing shared standards for AI safety, privacy protection, and ethical use while allowing for innovation and cultural diversity. The most successful policy approaches will likely be those that embrace technological progress while actively managing its disruptive effects. History suggests that societies that successfully navigate technological revolutions are those that adapt their institutions to harness new capabilities while preserving core social values. The industrial revolution eventually delivered unprecedented prosperity, but only after significant institutional innovations including public education, labor protections, and progressive taxation. The AI revolution will similarly require institutional creativity to ensure that technological progress translates into broadly shared human flourishing.
Summary
The AI revolution represents the latest chapter in humanity's complex relationship with technology - a relationship that has consistently transformed how we work, live, and understand ourselves. Throughout this examination, a central tension emerges between technological capability and human adaptation. While AI promises unprecedented productivity gains and potential solutions to humanity's greatest challenges, it also threatens significant disruption to labor markets, social structures, and perhaps even our understanding of what makes us uniquely human. This tension isn't new - similar anxieties accompanied the steam engine, electricity, and computers - but AI's ability to replicate cognitive functions previously considered exclusively human gives this revolution distinctive implications. The historical pattern suggests cause for cautious optimism. Previous technological revolutions initially concentrated benefits among a few while disrupting many lives, but eventually led to broadly shared prosperity through a combination of market adaptation and deliberate policy choices. For the AI revolution to follow this pattern rather than creating a permanently divided society, we must make conscious choices now. These include reimagining education to emphasize uniquely human capabilities, developing regulatory frameworks that encourage beneficial AI while preventing harmful applications, ensuring economic benefits are widely shared through appropriate tax and labor policies, and maintaining human judgment and values at the center of technological development. By learning from history while recognizing AI's unique characteristics, we can shape a future where technology enhances human flourishing rather than diminishing it.
Best Quote
Review Summary
Strengths: The book is described as thoughtful, well-documented, and interesting to read. It provides insights into the economic and business implications of AI and robots, and is considered forward-looking. Weaknesses: The reviewer found the writing style unappealing and the content not engaging enough to maintain interest, leading to a decision not to finish the book. There is also a critique of the book's exploration of creativity and emotional intelligence in the context of AI. Overall Sentiment: Mixed. While the book is acknowledged for its insightful content and forward-looking perspective, the reader's inability to engage with the writing style and content led to a less favorable overall impression. Key Takeaway: Despite its insightful analysis of AI's economic and business implications, the book's writing style and engagement level may not appeal to all readers, potentially limiting its accessibility and impact.
Trending Books
Download PDF & EPUB
To save this Black List summary for later, download the free PDF and EPUB. You can print it out, or read offline at your convenience.

The AI Economy
By Roger Bootle