
An Economist Walks into a Brothel
And Other Unexpected Places to Understand Risk
Categories
Business, Nonfiction, Psychology, Finance, Science, Economics, Audiobook, Management, Sociology, Money
Content Type
Book
Binding
Hardcover
Year
2019
Publisher
Penguin Publishing Group
Language
English
ASIN
0525533966
ISBN
0525533966
ISBN13
9780525533962
File Download
PDF | EPUB
An Economist Walks into a Brothel Plot Summary
Introduction
Risk is an inescapable part of our lives, yet most of us have a complicated relationship with it. We fear risk, avoid it when possible, and often fail to understand how it truly operates. But what if our conventional wisdom about risk is fundamentally flawed? Rather than seeing risk as something to be eliminated, we might better view it as a resource to be managed—a price we willingly pay for opportunity and reward. This fundamental shift in perspective forms the foundation for a revolutionary approach to decision-making in both professional and personal contexts. The exploration of risk management takes us far beyond the conventional realm of finance and into surprisingly illuminating territories. By examining risk through diverse lenses—from legal brothels in Nevada to big wave surfing, from Hollywood production studios to horse breeding farms—we gain unique insights that traditional economic approaches might miss. These unexpected case studies reveal how people across vastly different fields apply sophisticated risk management strategies, often without formal training in economics. Their practical wisdom, when systematized through financial economic principles, offers powerful tools that anyone can use to make better decisions in an increasingly uncertain world.
Chapter 1: The Price of Risk: What Brothels Teach Us About Uncertainty
Risk, at its core, represents the range of possible outcomes and the likelihood of each occurring. Most people naturally associate risk with negative possibilities—the chance of loss, failure, or harm. However, this limited view misses half the equation. In financial economics, risk encompasses the full spectrum of potential outcomes, both positive and negative. Understanding this broader definition is crucial because it reframes our entire approach to decision-making. The Nevada brothel industry provides a surprisingly illuminating window into risk management principles. Unlike illegal sex work, which carries significant risks of violence, disease, and arrest, legal brothels create a controlled environment where these dangers are systematically reduced. The fascinating economic discovery is that both sex workers and clients willingly pay substantial premiums for this risk reduction. Sex workers surrender approximately 50% of their earnings to the brothel, while clients pay about three times what they would in the illegal market—all to eliminate certain risks from the transaction. This pricing dynamic reveals something fundamental about how we value risk reduction. The brothel business model succeeds by isolating specific risks and assigning them clear monetary values. For sex workers, the risk of violence or arrest is worth half their potential income. For clients, the risk of legal troubles, blackmail, or disease is worth tripling their expenditure. This explicit price of risk creates transparency that allows all parties to make more informed decisions. The brothel example demonstrates how risk functions as a type of economic good that can be isolated, measured, priced, and traded. This perspective contrasts sharply with our typical approach of trying to eliminate risk entirely or ignoring it altogether. Instead, financial economics suggests viewing risk as something to be managed strategically, recognizing that eliminating all risk comes at a cost—often the loss of potential rewards. The legal brothel market also illustrates how risk management creates value. By providing mechanisms to reduce specific dangers while preserving the core transaction, brothels enable exchanges that might otherwise never occur. This principle extends far beyond this unusual example. In virtually every industry and personal decision context, effective risk management doesn't just protect against downside—it creates opportunities that wouldn't otherwise exist. When we understand risk as a price we pay for opportunity rather than simply a danger to avoid, we can approach decisions with greater clarity. This shift in perspective allows us to ask more productive questions: not "Should I take this risk?" but rather "How much risk should I take, and what's the most efficient way to manage it?" This reframing represents the first step toward mastering risk in any context.
Chapter 2: No Risk, No Reward: Defining Goals to Master Risk Taking
The adage "no risk, no reward" captures a fundamental economic truth: to gain anything worthwhile, we must accept some possibility of loss. However, this principle doesn't mean blindly embracing risk. Rather, it suggests that effective risk-taking requires clarity about what you're trying to achieve. The most common mistake people make is taking risks without a well-defined goal or clear understanding of the reward they seek. Financial economics offers a powerful framework for addressing this challenge through the concept of "risk-free." Before deciding how much risk to take, you must first define what constitutes a risk-free option for your specific situation—the path that provides certainty of achieving your goal. This becomes your baseline for comparison. For instance, if your goal is saving $3,000 for a family vacation next summer, a government bond or bank savings account represents your risk-free option. Anything else—stocks, cryptocurrencies, or speculative investments—introduces uncertainty but also the possibility of greater returns. This approach requires three critical steps. First, define your ultimate goal with precision. Second, identify the risk-free path to achieving that goal—the option that guarantees success, even if it's expensive or difficult. Third, determine whether the risk-free option is feasible or desirable. If not, you can strategically decide how much risk to introduce to make your goal attainable. This methodical process creates clarity that random risk-taking lacks. The case of Kat Cole, who rose from poverty to become COO of a billion-dollar company by age thirty, illustrates this principle. What appeared to be reckless decisions—dropping out of college to work at Hooters, later killing a major low-calorie product initiative at Cinnabon against industry trends—were actually calculated risks based on clear goals. When Cole faced the choice between continuing college or accepting international opportunities with Hooters, she recognized that her true goal wasn't a degree but a path to corporate leadership. The seemingly riskier option actually provided a more direct route to her objective. Similarly, when Cole took over Cinnabon during a sales decline, she rejected the industry trend toward healthier options. Rather than creating an artificial 599-calorie cinnamon roll, she doubled down on the company's indulgent identity while making the existing product available in a smaller size. This strategy, which appeared to contradict conventional wisdom, proved successful because Cole had clearly defined her goal: increasing sales rather than merely offering lower-calorie options. The principle applies equally to personal decisions. When buying a house, determining whether your goal is finding a forever home or making a profitable investment completely changes your risk strategy. For a forever home, paying above market might reduce the risk of losing a bidding war. For an investment property, underbidding protects against overpaying. Without goal clarity, people often take the wrong risks, leading to regret regardless of outcome.
Chapter 3: Measuring Risk: How to Quantify the Unpredictable
Measuring risk represents one of humanity's most significant intellectual achievements. Until the Renaissance and Enlightenment, most people believed uncertainty was determined by divine forces and couldn't be measured. The revolutionary work of mathematicians like Pascal, Fermat, and Bernoulli changed this perception by developing tools to quantify probabilities, first for controlled situations like dice games and later for real-world scenarios. Modern risk measurement typically involves analyzing historical data to project future possibilities. For example, by examining stock market returns from 1950 to 2018, we can identify patterns in how much prices typically rise or fall each month. Financial economists often represent this information using statistical models like the normal distribution or "bell curve," where most outcomes cluster around the average, with extreme results becoming increasingly rare. This approach allows risk to be expressed as a single number—volatility or standard deviation—representing how widely outcomes typically vary. However, real-world risk rarely follows such neat patterns. The movie business provides an instructive example of how risk measurement can go wrong. Despite decades of attempts to predict box office performance using sophisticated algorithms, Hollywood remains notoriously unpredictable. The distribution of film profits isn't normally distributed but heavily skewed—most movies lose money, while a few become massive hits. This "long tail" distribution makes traditional risk metrics unreliable, as they underestimate both the likelihood and magnitude of extreme outcomes. Ryan Kavanaugh, who founded Relativity Media, claimed to have solved this problem with a proprietary Monte Carlo simulation that could accurately predict which films would succeed. His model seemed revolutionary, securing hundreds of millions in investment from sophisticated hedge funds. For a time, his predictions appeared accurate, delivering solid returns. But eventually, like other supposed Hollywood risk models, it failed spectacularly, contributing to Relativity's bankruptcy in 2016. What went wrong? First, Kavanaugh's model relied on historical data that quickly became outdated in a rapidly changing industry. The emergence of streaming platforms, shifting international markets, and evolving consumer preferences meant past performance became an increasingly poor predictor of future results. Second, the fundamental nature of the movie business—with its skewed distribution and winner-take-all dynamics—defies simplification into reliable probability estimates. This doesn't mean risk measurement is worthless. Despite its limitations, data-driven analysis remains our best tool for making sense of uncertainty. Even imperfect models provide more structure than pure intuition. The key is understanding what risk estimates can and cannot tell us. They offer a map of possible outcomes based on historical patterns, not a guarantee of future results. Just as a road map doesn't show every pothole but still helps navigate from one city to another, risk models provide guidance while requiring supplementary judgment and flexibility. The democratization of data and computing power has dramatically expanded our ability to measure risk in previously opaque domains. From Netflix's viewing recommendations to Google Maps' travel time estimates, algorithms now quantify uncertainties that once seemed unmeasurable. While these tools will never eliminate uncertainty entirely, they enable more informed decisions by making the invisible visible—transforming pure uncertainty into manageable risk.
Chapter 4: Rational Irrationality: Why We Misperceive Probabilities
Humans have a complicated relationship with probability. Even when risks are clearly defined, our perception of those risks often diverges significantly from mathematical reality. These systematic distortions affect everyday decisions from buying lottery tickets to investing in the stock market. Understanding these patterns of misperception is crucial for anyone attempting to make better risk decisions. One of the most powerful biases affecting risk perception is loss aversion—the tendency to feel losses more intensely than equivalent gains. When faced with potential losses, we often become risk-seeking, willing to take dangerous gambles to avoid a certain loss. Conversely, when facing potential gains, we typically become risk-averse, preferring certainty over potentially larger but uncertain rewards. This asymmetry explains behaviors like holding onto losing investments while selling winners prematurely. The "break-even effect" represents a particularly destructive manifestation of this bias. After experiencing a loss, people frequently take increasingly desperate risks attempting to recover their position. Professional poker player Phil Hellmuth attributes much of his success to avoiding this trap. While many skilled players loosen their standards and play more aggressively when losing, Hellmuth maintains discipline regardless of his current position. Research confirms this pattern extends beyond poker—studies of online gaming and financial trading consistently show people taking larger risks after losses than after gains. Our probability perceptions are also heavily influenced by how information is presented. When told a medical treatment "doubles your risk," the impression seems alarming—until you learn this means increasing from one case in 7,000 to two cases in 7,000. Similarly, the framing of "you can't win if you don't play" makes lottery participation seem reasonable despite astronomical odds against winning. These presentation effects explain why risk communication is fundamentally an exercise in power—those who control how probabilities are framed can significantly influence behavior. We consistently overestimate extremely unlikely events, particularly those that generate vivid mental images. This explains why terrorism or plane crashes generate disproportionate fear compared to more common dangers like car accidents. Simultaneously, we tend to discount small probability differences in the middle ranges (like between 40% and 45% chances) while placing enormous weight on the difference between 0% and 5% (possibility versus impossibility) or between 95% and 100% (near certainty versus absolute certainty). Research suggests we aren't inherently incapable of understanding probabilities—rather, our cognitive architecture evolved for processing frequencies ("one in twenty people") rather than abstract percentages ("5% of cases"). When information is presented as concrete frequencies rather than abstract probabilities, people demonstrate much more rational decision-making. This insight offers practical guidance for both communicating and interpreting risk information more effectively. The modern world, with its abundance of data and sophisticated predictive algorithms, offers unprecedented opportunities to improve risk decisions. However, these tools will only benefit us if we develop the literacy to interpret them accurately. Understanding our systematic biases allows us to implement safeguards against them—whether through formal training, seeking multiple perspectives, or deliberately recasting problems in terms that align better with our cognitive strengths.
Chapter 5: Risk Diversification: Finding Efficiency in Imperfect Markets
One of the most powerful risk management strategies is diversification—distributing resources across multiple investments to reduce overall volatility without sacrificing expected returns. This concept revolutionized finance after Harry Markowitz formalized it in 1952, earning him a Nobel Prize. Yet many people fail to apply this principle effectively, often paying too much for unnecessary risk. The essence of diversification lies in recognizing that not all risks require compensation. Risks specific to individual assets (idiosyncratic risk) can be eliminated through diversification, leaving only market-wide risks (systematic risk) that genuinely deserve risk premiums. For investors, this means holding many uncorrelated assets rather than concentrating in a few favorites. The resulting portfolio can deliver the same expected return with substantially less volatility—essentially providing a "free lunch" in risk-reward terms. The thoroughbred horse breeding industry illustrates both the potential and challenges of diversification in a specialized market. Despite investing enormous sums in breeding racehorses, the industry operates with remarkable inefficiency. Breeders routinely pay exorbitant stud fees for champion stallions like War Front ($250,000 per breeding) despite minimal evidence that such expensive pairings produce consistently superior racehorses. Research suggests higher stud fees actually correlate with lower racing earnings, indicating severe market dysfunction. This inefficiency stems from several factors. First, breeding focuses on short-term sales rather than long-term racing performance. Yearlings (one-year-old horses) sell primarily based on pedigree rather than actual racing potential, creating incentives to breed with famous stallions regardless of genetic compatibility. Second, the industry has grown increasingly concentrated, with nearly all modern thoroughbreds descending from a handful of stallions, particularly Northern Dancer. This inbreeding may enhance certain commercially valuable traits but reduces overall genetic diversity and potentially racing performance. The parallels to investment portfolios are striking. Just as investors might overconcentrate in a few popular stocks despite the benefits of broader diversification, horse breeders pursue fashionable bloodlines rather than complementary genetic combinations. In both cases, the pursuit of perceived "quality" trumps the statistical benefits of diversification. The result is increased risk without compensating rewards—the precise opposite of efficient risk management. Advanced genetic science offers potential solutions. Rather than pursuing famous bloodlines, breeders could use DNA analysis to match horses with complementary characteristics, balancing strengths and weaknesses to produce more consistently successful racehorses. This approach would likely reduce the premium paid to champion stallions while improving overall racing outcomes—a more efficient market structure benefiting the industry as a whole. This principle extends far beyond finance and horse breeding. Career diversification through "side hustles" protects against job-specific risks. Dating multiple people before committing to a relationship increases the odds of finding compatibility. Even friendship networks benefit from diversification across different social circles. In each case, the strategy reduces vulnerability to single-point failures without sacrificing—and sometimes enhancing—expected outcomes. The challenge lies in overcoming our natural tendency toward concentration. The allure of picking the next Apple or breeding the next Secretariat remains powerful despite overwhelming evidence that diversification produces better risk-adjusted results. Effective risk management requires balancing this instinctive pursuit of outsized rewards with systematic protection against unnecessary risks.
Chapter 6: Risk Management: Hedging, Insurance, and Finding Balance
Risk management extends beyond diversification to include strategies that deliberately transform risk profiles. Two complementary approaches—hedging and insurance—offer powerful tools for controlling exposure to uncertain outcomes. Understanding when and how to apply these techniques represents a crucial skill for navigating an increasingly volatile world. Hedging involves deliberately giving up potential gains to reduce potential losses. The simplest hedging strategy is investing in both risky and risk-free assets, like dividing retirement savings between stocks and bonds. This approach sacrifices some upside potential in exchange for greater certainty—a trade-off many find worthwhile as they approach retirement or other financial goals. More sophisticated hedges might involve offsetting positions, like airlines purchasing futures contracts to lock in fuel prices regardless of market fluctuations. Arnold Donald, CEO of Carnival Cruise Line, exemplifies strategic hedging in both career and business contexts. Growing up in poverty in segregated New Orleans, Donald approached life decisions with remarkable clarity about risk-reward trade-offs. Rather than pursuing maximum potential rewards, he consistently sought to "maximize the probability of success"—even if it meant accepting slightly lower upside. This strategy informed decisions from education (securing scholarships rather than taking loans) to business (rolling out new technologies gradually despite potential competitive advantages from faster implementation). Insurance represents a different approach to risk management. Unlike hedging, which reduces both upside and downside, insurance preserves upside potential while transferring downside risk to another party in exchange for a premium. This asymmetrical protection makes insurance particularly valuable for catastrophic but unlikely risks. The challenge lies in determining whether the premium justifies the protection—a calculation requiring clear understanding of both the probability and magnitude of potential losses. Financial options function as a form of insurance in investment markets. Put options, for instance, guarantee the ability to sell assets at a predetermined price regardless of market conditions, protecting against downside while preserving upside (minus the premium cost). The development of sophisticated option pricing models by Black, Scholes, and Merton in the 1970s revolutionized risk management by providing consistent frameworks for valuing these protections. Both hedging and insurance can be inverted to increase rather than decrease risk. Leverage (borrowing to enhance investment exposure) functions as negative hedging, amplifying both potential gains and losses. Similarly, selling insurance or options can generate steady premium income but creates exposure to potentially catastrophic losses. These strategies explain how apparently conservative institutions can suddenly face existential threats during market disruptions. The appropriate balance between risk retention and risk transfer depends on specific circumstances and goals. For core necessities like retirement income or household protection, insurance and hedging play crucial roles. For discretionary goals where failure is tolerable, accepting more unhedged risk may maximize expected outcomes. The key insight is that risk management isn't about eliminating all uncertainty—it's about transforming risk profiles to align with specific objectives and preferences. Effective risk management requires recognizing that safety mechanisms sometimes encourage greater risk-taking—a phenomenon economists call "moral hazard." Just as improved automobile safety features lead to faster driving, financial risk protections can enable excessive risk-taking. This dynamic explains why big wave surfers now tackle 80-foot monsters that would have been unthinkable before modern rescue equipment, and why financial institutions took unprecedented leverage before the 2008 crisis. The solution isn't abandoning safety innovations but developing appropriate guardrails and awareness around their limitations.
Chapter 7: Embracing Uncertainty: Preparing for the Unplannable
Even the most sophisticated risk management cannot eliminate fundamental uncertainty—the possibility of events we never anticipated or considered. The military, which invests enormous resources in planning, provides powerful lessons on preparing for this unavoidable reality. As Dwight Eisenhower observed, "Plans are worthless, but planning is everything." General H.R. McMaster's experience during the 1991 Gulf War illustrates this principle. Leading Eagle Troop in the Battle of 73 Easting, McMaster encountered conditions nothing like what planners had anticipated. A sandstorm provided unexpected concealment, enemy positions differed from intelligence estimates, and battlefield dynamics evolved rapidly. McMaster's success came not from rigidly following plans but from adapting to emerging realities while maintaining core mission objectives—a flexibility enabled by thorough training and clear strategic understanding. The battle's aftermath revealed competing lessons. Some military leaders concluded that superior technology had "lifted the fog of war," making future conflicts predictable and controllable. This perspective, which McMaster called the "vampire fallacy," led to reducing force size and centralizing command structures. Yet McMaster and other historians drew opposite conclusions—that warfare remains fundamentally uncertain despite technological advantages, requiring decentralized decision-making and well-trained troops empowered to adapt. This tension between planning and flexibility extends far beyond military contexts. Financial models before the 2008 crisis suggested the "Great Moderation" had eliminated severe economic downturns—a dangerous illusion that encouraged excessive risk-taking. Similarly, seemingly robust supply chains proved vulnerable to unprecedented disruptions during the COVID-19 pandemic. In each case, mistaking risk reduction for uncertainty elimination created dangerous complacency. Preparing for uncertainty requires four key elements identified by military strategist Meir Finkel. First, create environments that encourage diverse perspectives and challenge prevailing assumptions. Second, maintain technological diversity rather than relying exclusively on supposedly superior systems. Third, establish mechanisms for rapid learning and information sharing when unexpected events occur. Fourth, develop leaders with the mental flexibility to adapt strategies when circumstances change. These principles apply equally to personal decisions. When changing careers, moving to a new city, or entering relationships, we cannot anticipate every possibility. Effective preparation involves developing core capabilities, maintaining option value, and cultivating adaptability rather than attempting to plan for every contingency. Just as military units train intensively for diverse scenarios rather than single predicted outcomes, we should focus on building transferable skills and resilience. Risk management tools—from diversification to insurance—remain valuable despite their limitations. The planning process itself creates value by forcing us to clarify objectives, identify key vulnerabilities, and consider potential responses. The error lies not in using these tools but in forgetting their inherent limitations—in mistaking the map for the territory. Ultimately, embracing uncertainty means accepting that control is always partial and temporary. The most effective approach combines rigorous analysis of measurable risks with humble recognition of fundamental uncertainty. This balanced perspective enables confident action without the illusion of complete predictability—allowing us to move forward purposefully in an inherently uncertain world.
Summary
The exploration of risk across diverse domains reveals a consistent pattern: successful risk-takers rarely eliminate uncertainty but rather transform it through strategic management. Whether in legal brothels, big wave surfing, horse breeding, or military operations, those who thrive amid uncertainty share common approaches: they clearly define goals, measure relevant risks, diversify unnecessary exposures, hedge or insure against critical threats, and maintain flexibility for the truly unexpected. This framework offers a powerful alternative to both reckless gambling and paralyzed risk-aversion. The most profound insight may be that risk itself is neither good nor bad but simply the price we pay for opportunity. Like any price, it can be negotiated, reduced through clever strategy, or occasionally avoided altogether—but it cannot be eliminated from a life worth living. By applying the scientific principles of financial economics to everyday decisions, we gain both the analytical clarity to identify unnecessary risks and the strategic tools to take necessary ones more effectively. This balanced approach enables us to navigate an increasingly uncertain world not with fear but with informed confidence, turning the management of risk from a specialized technical skill into a fundamental life competency accessible to everyone.
Best Quote
“Unusual markets often provide the clearest insight into how risk is assessed, bought, and sold. Because nothing is hidden in markets like sex work, the subtleties that exist in all markets are made obvious. This is why we can learn the most by studying how business is conducted at the edges of the economy and apply that knowledge to more typical economic transactions.” ― Allison Schrager, An Economist Walks into a Brothel: And Other Unexpected Places to Understand Risk
Review Summary
Strengths: The book includes engaging anecdotes and covers a wide range of topics, such as brothels, Cinnabon, and big wave surfing, to illustrate financial economics concepts. The initial storyline is particularly effective in conveying the author's points. Weaknesses: The reviewer expected more from the book, suggesting that it may lack depth or advanced insights. The presentation of financial economic terms in non-traditional contexts is noted as surprising, implying a potential disconnect for those seeking more conventional financial discussions. Overall Sentiment: Mixed Key Takeaway: The book offers an accessible introduction to financial economics through diverse and entertaining examples, but may not fully satisfy those seeking in-depth or traditional economic analysis.
Trending Books
Download PDF & EPUB
To save this Black List summary for later, download the free PDF and EPUB. You can print it out, or read offline at your convenience.

An Economist Walks into a Brothel
By Allison Schrager