
Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy
Essential analysis on where the world economy is headed
Categories
Business, Nonfiction, Philosophy, History, Economics, Politics, Classics, Sociology, Society, Political Science
Content Type
Book
Binding
Paperback
Year
1994
Publisher
Routledge
Language
English
ASIN
0415107628
ISBN
0415107628
ISBN13
9780415107624
File Download
PDF | EPUB
Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy Plot Summary
Synopsis
Introduction
How does capitalism evolve, and what forces drive its transformation? This question lies at the heart of understanding modern economic systems and their future trajectories. Schumpeter's theoretical framework offers a distinctive perspective that challenges conventional economic wisdom by positioning creative destruction as the essential feature of capitalism—a process where innovation continuously revolutionizes economic structures from within, destroying old patterns while creating new ones. This evolutionary approach stands in stark contrast to static equilibrium models that dominated economic thinking. The theory provides a structured understanding of several interconnected elements: capitalism's historical performance and inherent dynamism, the changing nature of entrepreneurship, the role of intellectuals in shaping anti-capitalist sentiment, and the gradual social transformation that may lead toward socialism. By examining these components through a historical-sociological lens rather than purely economic analysis, Schumpeter develops a comprehensive framework for understanding not just how capitalism functions, but how it transforms itself and society through its own success, potentially creating conditions for its eventual replacement by some form of socialism.
Chapter 1: Creative Destruction as Capitalism's Core Process
Creative destruction represents the essential fact about capitalism—it is what capitalism consists in and what every capitalist enterprise must live with. Unlike traditional economic theory that focuses on how capitalism administers existing structures, Schumpeter's framework emphasizes capitalism's inherently dynamic character. The capitalist process is fundamentally evolutionary, characterized by incessant innovation that revolutionizes economic structures from within, continuously destroying the old while creating the new. This process operates through several interconnected mechanisms. Innovation—whether in products, production methods, organizational forms, or markets—disrupts existing equilibria and creates temporary monopolistic advantages. These innovations do not emerge randomly but are systematically generated by the competitive pursuit of profit. Entrepreneurs introduce new combinations that render existing ones obsolete, creating extraordinary profits that attract imitators. As innovations diffuse through the economy, initial advantages erode, prompting another round of innovation. This cyclical process drives economic development while simultaneously creating both prosperity and instability. The competition that matters in capitalism is not the textbook type focused on marginal price adjustments within fixed constraints. Rather, it is competition from new commodities, technologies, sources of supply, and types of organization that strikes at the foundations of existing firms. When a department store threatens small retailers, or when aluminum challenges copper, the pressure does not operate through small adjustments in price but through fundamental threats to survival. This competition acts even before it materializes—the mere threat of innovation disciplines firms before actual entry occurs. Consider the transformation of retail in the twentieth century as an illustration of creative destruction. Traditional small shops were displaced by department stores, which were later challenged by discount chains, followed by big-box retailers, and eventually online commerce. Each wave created enormous value while simultaneously rendering previous business models obsolete. Workers, skills, locations, and capital associated with older forms became devalued, creating both progress and dislocation. This pattern repeats across industries—from transportation to entertainment to manufacturing—as innovation continuously reshapes the economic landscape. The social consequences of creative destruction are profound and ambivalent. While generating unprecedented improvements in living standards over time, the process creates significant disruption for workers, communities, and industries caught on the wrong side of change. The capitalist achievement consists not primarily in providing more silk stockings for queens but in bringing factory products within reach of ordinary people in exchange for steadily decreasing amounts of effort. Yet this achievement comes with recurring cycles of boom and bust, job displacement, and regional decline that generate social and political resistance to the very process that drives prosperity. Understanding capitalism requires recognizing this dual nature—its unmatched capacity for material progress alongside its inherent tendency toward creative destruction. This perspective explains why capitalism generates both growth and instability, why it produces both wealth and insecurity, and why it simultaneously attracts both fervent defenders and passionate critics. The capitalist engine is powerful but disruptive, creating conditions that both sustain and undermine its social foundations.
Chapter 2: The Historical Performance of Capitalism
Capitalism's historical performance has been remarkable when measured by the rate of increase in total output and improvement in living standards. From 1870 to 1930, output in advanced economies grew at unprecedented rates—approximately 3.7 percent annually in the United States, with manufacturing expanding even faster at 4.3 percent. This translated to a doubling of average real income per capita every fifty years, a transformation that dramatically improved material conditions for ordinary people. Unlike previous economic systems that primarily benefited elites, capitalism's signature achievement was making previously luxury goods accessible to the masses. This economic performance was not accidental but systematically connected to capitalism's evolutionary process. The capitalist engine generated growth through waves of innovation that continuously transformed production methods, created new products, and opened new markets. Industries that appeared monopolistic or oligopolistic often delivered the most impressive improvements in quality and reductions in price over time. From 1890 to 1929, for instance, the price of aluminum fell to approximately 12 percent of its original level while output increased dramatically. Similar patterns occurred in automobiles, chemicals, electronics, and other sectors dominated by large enterprises. Traditional economic analysis often misses this dynamic by focusing on static efficiency rather than long-term development. Perfect competition models examine how firms respond to given prices and technologies but ignore how innovation creates and destroys market structures. This approach fails to recognize that restrictive business practices—patents, temporary secrecy, exclusive contracts—often facilitate the investments necessary for technological progress. What appears as monopolistic behavior in the short term may actually enable long-term innovation that ultimately benefits consumers through better products and lower prices. The historical evidence contradicts simplistic narratives about monopoly power and economic stagnation. Industries dominated by large firms with significant market power—precisely those most criticized by traditional competition theory—frequently delivered the most impressive performance in terms of productivity growth and price reduction. These firms could afford the research departments, capital investments, and marketing capabilities necessary to develop and commercialize innovations. The monopoly profits they temporarily enjoyed served as both incentives for innovation and sources of funding for further advances. Capitalism's performance is particularly striking when viewed from the perspective of ordinary consumers rather than abstract economic metrics. The system's achievement consists not in providing luxury goods to elites but in democratizing consumption by making previously scarce products widely available. Items that were once exclusive to the wealthy—from indoor plumbing to automobiles to telecommunications—became accessible to the middle and working classes. This mass production for mass consumption represented a fundamental break from previous economic systems that primarily served elite interests. This historical record provides essential context for evaluating capitalism's social and political implications. While the system generated significant inequalities and periodic crises, it simultaneously produced unprecedented improvements in material conditions across social classes. Understanding this dual nature—capitalism as both disruptive and progressive—is crucial for assessing its evolution and potential transformation. The same mechanisms that drive economic development also create social tensions that shape capitalism's institutional evolution.
Chapter 3: Entrepreneurial Function and Its Obsolescence
The entrepreneurial function lies at the heart of capitalist development but is gradually becoming obsolete through capitalism's own success. This function consists in carrying out "new combinations"—introducing novel products, production methods, markets, sources of supply, or forms of industrial organization. The entrepreneur is not merely a manager or capitalist but specifically the agent who implements innovation, breaking established patterns and overcoming resistance to change. This role requires special aptitudes: vision to see beyond existing routines, courage to face uncertainty, and leadership to mobilize resources in new directions. This function operates through several distinct mechanisms. First, entrepreneurs identify opportunities created by scientific discoveries, changing consumer preferences, or market inefficiencies. They then assemble the necessary resources—capital, labor, materials—often against skepticism from established interests. Finally, they implement their vision through new business ventures or transformations of existing enterprises. The rewards for successful innovation come primarily through temporary monopoly profits before competitors imitate the innovation, driving the entrepreneur to seek further innovations to maintain advantage. The entrepreneurial function is becoming obsolete through two parallel developments. First, innovation itself is being routinized and bureaucratized. Large corporations establish research and development departments that systematically generate improvements according to predictable schedules. Teams of specialists replace the individual entrepreneur, while sophisticated planning techniques reduce the uncertainty once navigated through personal judgment. The romance of commercial adventure gives way to calculated management, transforming innovation from heroic act to organizational process. Second, the social environment has become increasingly accustomed to economic change. While innovation once faced strong resistance from established interests and traditional attitudes, modern society expects and accepts continuous transformation. Consumers eagerly anticipate new products rather than clinging to familiar ones. Workers recognize the need for occupational mobility rather than lifetime employment in single trades. This reduction in social resistance removes a key obstacle that entrepreneurs historically had to overcome, diminishing the need for their distinctive leadership qualities. Consider how technological innovation has evolved from individual breakthroughs to systematic processes. Early automobiles emerged from the workshops of individual inventors like Henry Ford, who personally directed their enterprises and made crucial decisions based on intuition and vision. Modern vehicle development, by contrast, involves teams of engineers, designers, and marketers following established procedures for product development. Similar transitions occurred across industries—from chemicals to electronics to software—as entrepreneurial functions became embedded in organizational routines rather than dependent on exceptional individuals. This transformation parallels historical changes in other domains. Just as medieval warfare evolved from individual combat dominated by knights to modern mechanized operations where personal heroism matters less, economic leadership has shifted from heroic entrepreneurs to professional management teams. The captain of industry gives way to the corporate executive, just as the warrior chief gave way to the military officer. This represents not merely a change in personnel but a fundamental transformation in how economic development occurs—a shift that ultimately threatens the social position of the bourgeois class that depends on entrepreneurial vitality for its legitimacy and renewal.
Chapter 4: The Intellectual Class and Anti-Capitalist Sentiment
The intellectual class occupies a unique position in capitalist society as both its product and its critic. Intellectuals—defined as those who wield the power of the spoken and written word without direct responsibility for practical affairs—emerge as a distinct social group precisely through capitalism's expansion of education and communication. Unlike other classes defined by economic function, intellectuals are characterized by their critical attitude and their role in shaping public opinion. Their position as observers rather than participants in economic processes gives them both freedom and incentive to scrutinize existing arrangements. Capitalism creates and nurtures this critical class through several mechanisms. First, it expands education, particularly higher education, producing more graduates than the economy can absorb in professional positions. This creates a pool of educated individuals who naturally gravitate toward intellectual occupations. Second, capitalism provides the material means for intellectual activity—printing presses, mass media, leisure time—while simultaneously removing traditional restraints on criticism. Third, the rationalist mentality fostered by capitalism undermines reverence for tradition and encourages critical questioning of all institutions. The hostility of intellectuals toward capitalism stems not primarily from economic self-interest but from their structural position and psychological disposition. As professional critics of society, intellectuals gain prestige by identifying flaws in established institutions. Capitalism provides an ideal target because its practical orientation contrasts with intellectual values of aesthetic refinement and theoretical consistency. Even when capitalism delivers material prosperity, intellectuals focus on its contradictions, inequalities, and cultural deficiencies. Their criticism is not necessarily based on personal grievances but on their role as society's critical conscience. This critical attitude finds receptive audiences among various groups. Workers experiencing economic hardship naturally respond to critiques of the system. The educated middle class, sharing intellectual values, is susceptible to arguments about capitalism's philistinism or injustice. Even business leaders may be influenced by intellectual critiques, especially when framed in terms of efficiency or progress rather than radical transformation. The intellectual thus serves as a catalyst, articulating and amplifying discontent that might otherwise remain inchoate. The relationship between intellectuals and political movements illustrates their influence. Labor movements were not created by intellectuals but received from them theories, slogans, and a sense of historical mission. Similarly, intellectuals have shaped public policy by staffing government agencies, writing speeches, advising politicians, and influencing public opinion. While rarely holding power themselves, they define the terms of political debate and the moral framework within which policies are evaluated. Their influence extends to bureaucracies, particularly as government expands and recruits educated personnel. Capitalism thus faces a paradoxical situation: it produces and sustains a class structurally disposed to criticize it. Unlike previous social systems that effectively suppressed criticism, capitalism's own values of freedom and rationality prevent it from silencing its critics. The bourgeoisie defends intellectual freedom even when it disapproves of how that freedom is used, because restrictions on criticism would undermine the liberal institutions on which capitalism depends. This represents a fundamental vulnerability in the capitalist order—it cannot control the intellectual sector without violating its own principles.
Chapter 5: Capitalism's Social Transformation
The capitalist process transforms not only economic structures but also the social and cultural foundations that initially supported its development. This transformation occurs gradually but cumulatively, altering institutions, values, and social relations in ways that ultimately undermine capitalism's own stability. Understanding this process requires examining how capitalism interacts with non-economic aspects of society—family structures, cultural attitudes, political arrangements—that provide its essential context. Capitalism initially emerged within pre-capitalist institutional frameworks that provided stability and legitimacy. In the absolute monarchies of the 17th and 18th centuries, and later in constitutional systems, the bourgeoisie gained economic power while political leadership remained largely in the hands of aristocratic or traditional elites. This division of labor—economic power for the bourgeoisie, political authority for the aristocracy—created a stable symbiosis that suited both groups. The bourgeoisie focused on business while the aristocracy, with its prestige and tradition of leadership, managed the state and provided social coherence. This arrangement reflected fundamental differences between bourgeois and aristocratic mentalities. The aristocrat was trained to command, fight, and rule—qualities that transferred readily to political leadership even as the economic basis of aristocratic power declined. The bourgeois, by contrast, developed skills in calculation, management, and rational organization that did not easily translate into political authority. The ledger and cost calculation, essential for business success, confined rather than expanded the bourgeois outlook. Except in limited contexts like city management, the bourgeois class proved ill-equipped for political leadership. As capitalism develops, it gradually erodes the non-capitalist elements that initially protected it. The bourgeois family firm, once the foundation of capitalist enterprise, gives way to the impersonal corporation. Property ownership becomes dematerialized as shareholders replace active proprietors, while contracts become standardized rather than individually negotiated. These changes diminish the emotional attachment to capitalist institutions that once motivated their defense. Absentee ownership does not inspire the same loyalty as personal property, leaving capitalist institutions without committed defenders. The transformation extends to cultural values and social attitudes. Capitalism's rationalism challenges traditional beliefs and religious values that once legitimized social hierarchies and economic inequalities. Its emphasis on efficiency and material progress conflicts with heroic or romantic ideals that previously inspired social cohesion. Even the bourgeoisie itself becomes increasingly skeptical of capitalist values, adopting critical attitudes toward business practices and materialistic goals. The children of successful entrepreneurs often turn toward intellectual, artistic, or political pursuits rather than continuing family businesses. Political changes further undermine capitalism's position. Democratic expansion gives power to masses with limited stake in capitalist institutions, while bureaucratic growth creates state agencies that may pursue goals at odds with business interests. International relations also shift, as the pacifist tendencies of commercial classes conflict with nationalist or imperialist ambitions. These political transformations occur gradually but cumulatively alter the institutional framework within which capitalism has operated, creating conditions increasingly favorable to socialist alternatives.
Chapter 6: The Transition Toward Socialism
The transition from capitalism to socialism represents not a revolutionary rupture but a gradual evolution through which capitalist institutions are progressively modified and socialized. This process occurs not primarily because of capitalism's economic failure—indeed, capitalism has demonstrated remarkable productive capacity—but through social and political transformations that undermine its institutional foundations and create conditions favorable to socialist organization. Understanding this transition requires examining both the mechanisms driving change and the likely characteristics of the emerging system. The entrepreneurial function, which has been the driving force of capitalist development, is gradually becoming obsolete as innovation becomes routinized and bureaucratized. Large corporations increasingly resemble public administrations rather than private enterprises, with professional managers replacing individual entrepreneurs. As the personal element in business diminishes, so does the social justification for private ownership. The corporation already represents a partial socialization of ownership, with shareholders exercising little real control over enterprise operations. This evolution naturally points toward further socialization and eventual public management. Simultaneously, capitalism creates social groups hostile to its continuation. The intellectual class, nurtured by capitalist prosperity and education, develops a critical attitude toward the system that sustains it. Labor organizations gain strength and political influence, while the middle class becomes increasingly dependent on salaried employment rather than property ownership. Even the capitalist class loses its vitality as inheritance replaces achievement and management becomes separated from ownership. These social changes erode support for capitalist institutions and create constituencies favorable to socialist alternatives. Political developments accelerate this transition. Democratic expansion gives power to groups with limited stake in capitalist property relations, while government intervention in economic affairs becomes increasingly necessary to address market failures and social problems. The modern state develops capacities for economic planning and management that make socialist organization technically feasible. International competition and conflicts further push toward national economic planning, especially during wartime when market mechanisms are partially suspended in favor of centralized control. The most likely path involves gradual socialization within an existing democratic framework. In countries with stable democratic institutions, certain sectors of the economy—banking, insurance, transportation, utilities, and some basic industries—could be nationalized while leaving other sectors to private enterprise. This incremental approach would allow democratic processes to adapt to changing economic arrangements without revolutionary disruption. The resulting system would combine elements of planning and market coordination, public and private ownership, in varying proportions depending on national conditions. Consider how this transition might affect different economic sectors. Essential public services and natural monopolies would likely come under direct public ownership and management. Basic industries producing standardized commodities might operate as public enterprises with significant autonomy. Consumer goods industries could remain largely private but subject to social regulation regarding working conditions, environmental impacts, and quality standards. Financial institutions would likely become public utilities directing investment according to democratically determined priorities while maintaining technical efficiency in resource allocation. The success of democratic socialism ultimately depends on creating institutions that can make rational economic decisions while remaining accountable to democratic processes. This requires balancing technical expertise with popular control, maintaining independent centers of power, and developing appropriate incentive systems for both managers and workers in socialized industries. The historical experience suggests that premature attempts at comprehensive socialization risk economic disruption and political authoritarianism, while gradual evolution within mature democratic frameworks offers greater promise for combining efficiency with social justice.
Chapter 7: Democracy as Competitive Leadership Selection
Democracy functions not as government by the people in any direct sense but as an institutional arrangement for arriving at political decisions through competitive struggle for the people's vote. This competitive theory of democracy shifts focus from the idealistic notion of popular sovereignty to the practical mechanism of leadership selection. Just as markets select economic leadership through competition for consumer preferences, democratic systems select political leadership through competition for electoral support. Understanding democracy in these terms clarifies both its strengths and limitations as a method of governance. The classical doctrine of democracy, rooted in 18th-century philosophy, presents democracy as a means to realize the common good by making the people decide issues through elected representatives. This theory assumes the existence of a definite common good that rational citizens can discern, leading to a coherent "will of the people" that representatives should implement. However, this conception faces fundamental problems: there is no uniquely determined common good on which all could agree, and citizens typically lack the rational engagement with political issues that the theory presupposes. The competitive theory offers a more realistic alternative. It recognizes that the primary function of voting is not to directly implement popular will but to produce government—to decide who the leading individuals shall be. Democracy becomes a method for selecting political leadership through competitive elections, with the people's role being to accept or reject those who would govern them. This arrangement creates accountability by allowing voters to remove underperforming leaders while providing incentives for responsiveness to public concerns. Leadership stands at the center of this conception of democracy. While the classical theory attributed unrealistic initiative to the electorate, the competitive theory acknowledges that collectives act primarily by accepting leadership. Political leaders formulate issues, shape public opinion, and organize latent group interests into political factors. They compete for votes much as entrepreneurs compete for consumers, offering political packages designed to attract maximum support. The democratic process operates through this competition, with political decisions emerging as by-products of the struggle for power rather than as direct expressions of popular will. This framework explains many features of democratic systems better than the classical theory. It accounts for the importance of party organizations, the role of opposition, and the function of parliamentary procedure. It also explains why democracy does not guarantee greater individual freedom or economic equality—these outcomes depend on the specific historical conditions and the values of successful political competitors, not on inherent properties of the democratic method itself. The relationship between democracy and socialism becomes clearer through this lens. Between democracy as a method of selecting leadership and socialism as a system of economic organization, there is neither necessary connection nor inherent incompatibility. Democratic processes could potentially select leadership committed to socialist economic arrangements, just as they could select leadership committed to capitalism. The success of democratic socialism ultimately depends on creating institutions that can make rational economic decisions while remaining accountable to democratic processes—a challenge that requires balancing technical expertise with popular control.
Summary
Schumpeter's theory of capitalist evolution provides a comprehensive framework for understanding how economic systems transform through their own internal dynamics. The key insight lies in recognizing capitalism not as a static system seeking equilibrium but as an evolutionary process driven by creative destruction—the continuous revolution of economic structures through innovation that simultaneously creates progress and instability. This perspective illuminates how capitalism's remarkable productive achievements contain the seeds of its own transformation, as entrepreneurial function becomes routinized, social structures evolve, and political arrangements shift toward greater democratic control of economic life. The evolutionary perspective offers profound implications for how we understand economic development and social change. Rather than seeing capitalism and socialism as fixed opposites, it reveals them as historical phases in an ongoing process of institutional evolution. Democracy itself emerges not as government by the people in any literal sense but as a competitive method for selecting leadership that can adapt to changing social conditions. This framework suggests that future economic arrangements will likely combine elements of market coordination with democratic planning, private initiative with social control, in ways that continue to evolve in response to technological change and social needs. The enduring value of this theory lies in its recognition that economic systems are not merely technical arrangements but fundamentally social creations that reflect and shape human values and relationships.
Best Quote
“Geniuses and prophets do not usually excel in professional learning, and their originality, if any, is often due precisely to the fact that they do not.” ― Joseph Aloïs Schumpeter, Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy
Review Summary
Strengths: The review provides a thought-provoking analysis of the relationship between capitalism, democracy, and societal values. It offers a unique perspective on the potential downfall of capitalism due to its perceived shortcomings in meeting human needs beyond material wealth. Weaknesses: The review lacks specific examples or evidence to support its claims, making it more of a philosophical reflection rather than a critical analysis of a particular book. Overall: The review presents an intriguing viewpoint on the interplay between capitalism, democracy, and human desires, making it a stimulating read for those interested in economic and political theory. However, readers seeking empirical evidence or a more structured argument may find it lacking in depth.
Trending Books
Download PDF & EPUB
To save this Black List summary for later, download the free PDF and EPUB. You can print it out, or read offline at your convenience.

Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy
By Joseph A. Schumpeter