
Inflation Matters
Inflationary Wave Theory, Its Impact on Inflation Past and Present ... and the Deflation Yet to Come
Categories
Economics
Content Type
Book
Binding
Kindle Edition
Year
2015
Publisher
Language
English
ASIN
B00RZ5GLZG
File Download
PDF | EPUB
Inflation Matters Plot Summary
Introduction
Throughout human history, the steady rise in prices has been a persistent economic reality, yet few truly understand its profound impact on society. Inflation—the increasing of prices over time—has been a powerful force shaping civilizations, financing wars, enabling government debt repayment, and redistributing wealth in ways often invisible to the average person. What's fascinating is that inflation isn't random; it follows distinct wave patterns that have repeated throughout centuries, with periods of sharp increases followed by consolidation phases of relative stability. The pages that follow explore this hidden rhythm of economic history, from ancient Rome's currency debasement to the hyperinflation of 1920s Germany, from post-WWII financial strategies to modern central bank policies. By understanding these historical patterns, we gain remarkable insight into our current economic situation and what might lie ahead. Whether you're a concerned saver watching your purchasing power erode, a student of economic history, or simply someone trying to make sense of today's financial headlines, the historical context provided here illuminates not just how inflation works, but why it matters—and to whom it matters most.
Chapter 1: The Origins of Inflation and Key Monetary Theories
Inflation has existed since the dawn of civilization, but understanding its fundamental nature requires exploring several competing theories. At its most basic level, inflation represents a general increase in prices of goods and services, or alternatively, a decline in the purchasing power of money. However, the definition has evolved significantly over time. In earlier centuries, inflation was defined primarily as an increase in the money supply beyond what was justified by a country's tangible resources. This view, pioneered by astronomers and economists like Copernicus in the 16th century, observed that when precious metals flooded into Europe from the New World, prices rose accordingly. This observation led to the Quantity Theory of Money, formally proposed by John Stewart Mill in 1848, which established that prices vary in proportion to the money supply, provided other factors remain stable. The famous economist John Maynard Keynes later introduced a more nuanced theory, suggesting inflation resulted from both demand-pull factors (when demand outstrips supply) and cost-push factors (when higher prices are forced upon us due to tax rises, devaluations, or commodity price rises). This perspective helped explain why inflation often accompanied wars, government spending programs, and commodity shortages—all of which were evident in the inflation spikes that followed World War I and the 1970s oil crisis. Meanwhile, the Reverend Thomas Robert Malthus proposed a longer-term theory connecting inflation to population growth. Writing in the late 18th century, Malthus suggested that the human population grew exponentially while resources grew arithmetically, creating competition that drove prices higher. This theory gained renewed interest as the world population nearly tripled between 1950 and 2013, coinciding with unprecedented global price increases. Today, economists recognize that all three theories—monetary, Keynesian, and Malthusian—likely influence inflation, but over different time frames. Monetary factors typically affect medium-term inflation, while Keynesian factors explain short-term price changes, and demographic factors drive long-term trends. This multi-dimensional understanding helps explain why inflation has been such a persistent feature of economic history, and why its effects reach far beyond simple price increases.
Chapter 2: Ancient to Medieval Inflation: Early Patterns and Lessons
Inflation has a much longer history than most people realize, dating back to ancient civilizations. Records from Babylonian times show marked price increases for barley during the reign of Alexander the Great (330-301 BC), likely resulting from the vast quantities of silver he brought back from his conquests. Similarly, the Roman Empire experienced three distinct waves of inflation, with the most severe occurring after 117 AD when Emperor Trajan and his successors began debasing the denarius coin by reducing its silver content from 95% to less than 1% within a century. These early inflationary episodes established a pattern that would repeat throughout history: inflation often follows a wave-like pattern of rising prices over extended periods (typically a century or more), followed by consolidation phases of relative stability. Sir Henry Phelps-Brown and Sheila Hopkins documented this pattern through painstaking research of household accounts in southern England, revealing distinct inflationary waves from 1180-1320, 1510-1650, and 1730-1815, each followed by periods of price stability. What's particularly striking is that each successive wave resulted in exponentially larger price increases than the previous one. The first medieval wave saw annual price increases averaging about 0.5%, while during the 1900-2000 wave, prices in the UK rose by a factor of 100. This escalation reflects mankind's increasing ability to exploit inflationary mechanisms over time, particularly through monetary expansion and debt. The transition between these inflationary waves has historically been turbulent, often triggered by calamities like war, population decline, or financial crises. For instance, the end of the first great inflation wave around 1320 coincided with massive population losses from famine and the Black Death, which wiped out between 25-40% of Europe's population. The Thirty Years War similarly marked the end of the second great wave around 1650. These early inflationary cycles established a crucial economic truth: inflation is not merely a monetary phenomenon but is deeply intertwined with demographic shifts, resource competition, and human psychology. Once prices break out of their historical range, an "inflationary mindset" takes hold across society, changing behaviors in ways that reinforce the trend. This historical pattern provides essential context for understanding later inflation episodes and suggests that our current era of persistent inflation may eventually give way to a new phase of price stability.
Chapter 3: World War I and the Weimar Hyperinflation Crisis (1914-1923)
World War I marked a critical turning point in inflation history, setting the stage for one of the most notorious hyperinflationary episodes ever recorded. When the war began in 1914, most major combatants—including Germany and the United Kingdom—suspended the gold standard that had previously constrained their money supplies. This decision allowed governments to finance the extraordinarily expensive war effort by creating massive amounts of new money. During the conflict, the German Reichsmark in circulation increased tenfold. While prices approximately doubled in both Germany and the UK during the war itself, the post-war period revealed dramatically different approaches to managing the resulting inflation. The UK decided to reinstate the link to gold and implemented policies to shrink the money supply, resulting in painful deflation throughout the 1920s. Germany's post-war Weimar Republic, burdened by massive war reparations demanded by the Treaty of Versailles, chose a different path with catastrophic consequences. The socialist German government continued expanding the money supply to finance generous welfare programs, education reforms, and economic reconstruction. Initially, this policy appeared successful—Berlin became Europe's tourist capital in the early 1920s, with lavish entertainment, nearly full employment, and booming businesses. However, by May 1921, a tipping point was reached. Public confidence in the currency collapsed, and people rushed to exchange their rapidly devaluing paper money for tangible goods. What followed was truly extraordinary. By late 1923, inflation reached 29,500 percent with prices doubling every few days. Workers were paid twice daily and rushed to spend their wages immediately. A 50 million mark note might buy a loaf of bread one day and be worthless the next. The situation was only resolved in November 1923 when the Rentenmark was introduced at an exchange rate of one trillion old Reichsmarks to one new Rentenmark. The consequences of this hyperinflation were profound and long-lasting. The middle class, whose wealth consisted largely of savings and fixed-income investments, was economically destroyed. Meanwhile, debtors (including the government) saw their obligations effectively wiped out. This massive transfer of wealth created deep social resentment that contributed to the rise of extremism in Germany. The memory of this traumatic episode has influenced German economic policy to this day, explaining the country's traditional emphasis on price stability and aversion to debt. The Weimar hyperinflation demonstrated how inflation, when taken to extremes, becomes much more than an economic phenomenon—it transforms into a destructive social force that can undermine the very foundations of society.
Chapter 4: Post-WWII Inflation as Government Debt Strategy (1945-1970s)
World War II left governments with unprecedented levels of debt, reaching an average of 123% of GDP across nations by 1947, and double that level in the United Kingdom. Unlike after World War I, when countries either attempted to deflate their economies to pay debts (like the UK) or allowed hyperinflation to effectively cancel them (like Germany), post-WWII governments adopted a more subtle strategy: persistent low-level inflation. The intellectual foundation for this approach came from the economic theories of John Maynard Keynes. Although Keynes himself had complex views on inflation, his work was often interpreted by post-war politicians as justifying moderate inflation to achieve full employment. Hugh Dalton, Britain's post-war Chancellor and a student of Keynes, understood the power of inflation as a method of taxation. He nationalized the Bank of England, giving government control over monetary policy, and maintained low interest rates while fostering moderate inflation—a strategy now recognized as "financial repression." The Bretton Woods monetary system, established in 1944 partly based on Keynes's ideas, created a mechanism for transmitting this inflation globally. By pegging most world currencies to the dollar (which was itself linked to gold), the United States could effectively export its inflation to other countries. The system also established the International Monetary Fund, which reduced the likelihood of deflationary periods by allowing countries to devalue their currencies rather than contracting their money supplies. This strategy proved remarkably effective. Within 25 years, Britain's real debt-to-GDP ratio had fallen from 237% to around 50%—despite the government never actually paying off the capital amount of its war debts. According to analysis by Ray Dalio of Bridgewater Associates, approximately 80% of this reduction came through inflation alone. The £26 billion debt from 1945 had, by 1970, been reduced in real terms to just £0.7 billion. What made this approach so politically palatable was its near invisibility. Unlike the hyperinflation of the Weimar Republic, which destroyed Germany's social fabric, post-war inflation was slow enough that few people recognized the wealth transfer taking place. Cash savings and fixed-income investments gradually lost purchasing power, while debtors (primarily governments) benefited enormously. As economist Hugh Dalton noted back in 1922, "The comparative acquiescence of public opinion in taxation by inflation is a measure of public ignorance of economic truths." This period established a new paradigm where inflation became an accepted feature of economic life—a tool used by governments to manage debt while maintaining social stability. The success of this strategy helps explain why the inflation mindset became so deeply embedded in economic thinking, and why so many governments continue to see moderate inflation as desirable rather than problematic.
Chapter 5: The Great Moderation and Recent Financial Crises (1980-2008)
After the tumultuous inflation of the 1970s, the world entered what economists later termed "The Great Moderation"—a period of declining inflation rates and increasing economic stability. From 1980 to 2000, inflation in G7 countries dropped from an average of 12% to nearly zero. This remarkable decline occurred globally, with even former high-inflation economies like Russia (which had experienced 874% inflation in 1993) seeing rates fall dramatically. Several factors contributed to this moderation. First, central bankers, led by Paul Volcker of the US Federal Reserve, deliberately engineered a recession in the early 1980s by raising interest rates to unprecedented levels—over 20% in the US. This painful but effective strategy broke the wage-price spiral that had developed during the 1970s. Second, China's 1994 decision to devalue its currency by a third and peg it to the US dollar flooded Western markets with increasingly affordable goods, creating a powerful disinflationary force. Technological advancement and globalization further suppressed inflation by increasing productivity, shortening supply chains, and allowing businesses to use just-in-time inventory methods. The rise of online shopping increased competition, further helping to keep prices in check. By the late 1990s, many economists and policymakers began to believe that they had finally conquered inflation—in 1999, UK Chancellor Gordon Brown famously claimed that the "boom and bust" business cycle was no more. However, the early 2000s saw inflation begin to rise again. After the dot-com crash of 2001, Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan cut interest rates from 7% to 1.75%, ushering in an era of cheap money. This triggered an explosion of debt across financial markets and among consumers. Money supply in the US grew over 6% annually from 2000-2007, and even faster in the UK. While much of this newly created money flowed into asset prices (housing, shares, commodities), some eventually leaked into consumer prices as well. This expansionary policy culminated in the financial crisis of 2008, which brought an abrupt end to the Great Moderation. The collapse of Lehman Brothers and other financial institutions caused a sudden contraction of economies worldwide as business and consumer confidence plummeted. Initially, this created strong deflationary pressure, with several major economies experiencing actual price declines in 2009. The legacy of the Great Moderation is complex. While it demonstrated that inflation could be controlled through monetary policy, it also sowed the seeds for the subsequent crisis by encouraging excessive risk-taking and debt accumulation. The period also fundamentally changed how central banks operated, with most adopting explicit inflation targets—typically around 2%—and using interest rate policies primarily to achieve these targets rather than to address broader economic imbalances.
Chapter 6: Current Inflation Dynamics and Government Influence
In today's world, inflation is largely a governmental choice rather than a random economic phenomenon. Switzerland has maintained an average inflation rate of just 0.7% since 2000 by setting a target range of 0-2%. By contrast, the UK has targeted 2% inflation (achieving 2.3%) while Russia and Turkey, with 5% targets, have averaged 10% and 20% respectively during the same period. These stark differences reveal how much control governments actually exert over inflation rates. Governments benefit substantially from inflation through what economists call "inflation tax." In the UK alone, this silent revenue stream was worth approximately £29 billion in 2014. When inflation exists, government tax revenues increase roughly in proportion to rising prices, while the real value of government debt decreases. This makes debt service payments more affordable without requiring unpopular direct tax increases or spending cuts. Beyond debt management, governments gain from inflation in numerous other ways. Personal tax revenues increase as inflation pushes more people into higher tax brackets—a phenomenon called "fiscal drag." In the UK, the number of higher-rate taxpayers more than doubled from 1.7 to 4.1 million over two decades. Business tax revenue similarly grows as inflation-driven profit increases push more companies over tax thresholds. Governments also benefit when inflation makes GDP appear higher after adjusting for price increases using deflators that typically understate true inflation. Governments influence inflation through multiple mechanisms. The most significant is by sanctioning an expanding money supply beyond what economic growth requires. In the UK, money supply has grown by 8.7% annually since World War II, while the economy has grown by just 2.3%. This excess money creation eventually manifests as price inflation. Governments can expand money supply directly through bond creation or quantitative easing, or indirectly by permitting private banks to expand credit. Other "inflation-friendly" policies include setting explicit inflation targets for central banks, controlling regulated prices (utilities, train fares, education costs), sponsoring borrowing programs like mortgage assistance schemes, engineering currency devaluations to make imports more expensive, and influencing wage agreements, particularly in the public sector. The net result of these policies is that even in today's supposedly low-inflation environment, inflation continues to function as a massive wealth transfer mechanism. It moves resources from savers, pensioners, and those on fixed incomes to debtors, governments, and financial speculators. What makes this transfer particularly effective is its invisibility—unlike direct taxation, most people don't realize how inflation gradually erodes their purchasing power. As economist John Maynard Keynes noted in 1922, inflation is "a form of taxation which the public find hard to identify." Understanding government's role in creating and sustaining inflation is crucial for recognizing how inflation shapes our economic landscape and why—despite periodic concerns about deflation—persistent low-level inflation remains the preferred policy of most governments around the world.
Chapter 7: The Coming Deflation: Transition to Price Stability
Despite central banks' current efforts to maintain positive inflation, powerful forces are emerging that point toward a future of price stability or even deflation. Historical analysis reveals that inflation typically follows wave patterns lasting roughly a century, followed by consolidation periods of similar length. With the current inflationary wave beginning around 1900, we may be approaching a major secular shift within the next few decades. Demographics represent the most significant deflationary force on the horizon. Although global population continues growing overall, births are below replacement levels in most developed countries. According to Deutsche Bank forecasts, world population will peak around 2050 and then decline. Japan, Russia, and Germany are already experiencing population decreases. This demographic shift creates a double deflationary impact: fewer people consuming goods and an aging population that naturally consumes less. The transition to this new era of price stability may not be smooth. Historically, the shift between inflationary and consolidation phases has involved significant economic disruption. According to economist Ronald Marcks, three conditions must be met for inflation to permanently end: the money supply must stabilize, latent inflation (created by previous monetary expansion) must be resolved, and debts must be restructured to sustainable levels. Currently, none of these conditions are met. The world's debt levels are still rising—estimated at over $223 trillion in 2012 and significantly higher today. In developed countries, debt averages nearly four times annual GDP. For the UK, total public, corporate, and private debt amounts to approximately £300,000 per household, against average household income of just £30,000. Such leverage ratios are clearly unsustainable long-term. Two possible scenarios might trigger the transition to price stability. One involves a bond market crisis where government debt becomes unserviceable, triggering cascading defaults across financial markets. This would destroy a significant portion of the money supply and create a deflationary shock. An alternative scenario is a planned restructuring similar to the "Chicago Plan" proposed by economists in the 1930s, which would transfer money creation power from private banks to a governmental body and write off significant portions of existing debt. Following this transition period, the world could enter a consolidation phase of relative price stability lasting into the 22nd century. In this new environment, prices would not remain static but would trend slightly downward due to technological and efficiency improvements. Workers would be incentivized to improve productivity to gain wage increases rather than expecting automatic inflation adjustments. Business would likely prosper in this more stable environment, though the financial sector would shrink significantly. The implications for wealth management are profound. Different assets will perform very differently during these phases. In the near term, central banks' determination to maintain positive inflation supports asset prices like shares and property. During any transition crisis, wealth destruction would be widespread, with precious metals possibly providing temporary safety. In the subsequent consolidation phase, returns would be lower but more sustainable, with money returning to its original purpose as a store of value rather than a speculative tool. Whether this transition happens gradually or through crisis remains to be seen, but the historical pattern suggests that our current era of persistent inflation will eventually give way to a new phase of greater price stability—with profound implications for economies, governments, and individuals alike.
Summary
Throughout the historical waves of inflation we've examined, a clear pattern emerges: inflation is not merely a monetary phenomenon but a complex social and political construct that transfers wealth in predictable ways. From ancient Rome's currency debasement to Weimar Germany's hyperinflation, from post-war financial repression to modern central bank targeting, inflation has consistently served as a mechanism for governments and debtors to reduce their obligations at the expense of savers and those on fixed incomes. This wealth transfer occurs whether inflation runs at 1000% or 2%, differing only in visibility and speed. The insights from this historical exploration provide valuable perspective for navigating our economic future. First, recognize that inflation is largely a governmental choice, not an economic inevitability—countries that want low inflation achieve it. Second, understand that demographic trends and debt levels suggest we may be approaching the end of the current inflationary wave, though the transition could be turbulent. Finally, prepare for a potential future where money returns to being primarily a store of value rather than an instrument of wealth transfer—a world where productivity improvements rather than monetary manipulation drive prosperity. By understanding these historical patterns, we gain not just economic insight but a deeper appreciation of how monetary systems shape society itself.
Best Quote
Review Summary
Strengths: The book simplifies a complex and often dull subject, making it accessible to a broad audience. It provides clear explanations of inflation, its causes, and its effects on the economy and society. The author is noted for his inquisitive nature and willingness to challenge conventional wisdom, supported by his background in psychology and market research. Weaknesses: Not explicitly mentioned. Overall Sentiment: Enthusiastic Key Takeaway: "Inflation Matters" effectively demystifies the topic of inflation, presenting it in an engaging and understandable manner while offering a fresh perspective on its patterns and implications. The author's analytical approach and diverse expertise contribute to the book's credibility and appeal.
Trending Books
Download PDF & EPUB
To save this Black List summary for later, download the free PDF and EPUB. You can print it out, or read offline at your convenience.

Inflation Matters
By Pete Comley