
Political Order and Political Decay
From the Industrial Revolution to the Globalization of Democracy
Categories
Nonfiction, Philosophy, History, Economics, Politics, Audiobook, Sociology, Society, Political Science, World History
Content Type
Book
Binding
Hardcover
Year
2014
Publisher
Farrar, Straus and Giroux
Language
English
ASIN
0374227357
ISBN
0374227357
ISBN13
9780374227357
File Download
PDF | EPUB
Political Order and Political Decay Plot Summary
Introduction
Throughout human history, societies have grappled with a fundamental challenge: how to create political systems that both exercise power effectively and constrain that power from becoming tyrannical. This tension has shaped civilizations across continents and centuries, from ancient China to modern America. The struggle to build functional states while simultaneously developing mechanisms to check their authority represents one of humanity's most profound political achievements. The evolution of political order isn't a simple march toward democracy or any single system. Rather, it's a complex interplay between three critical institutions: the state itself, which concentrates and deploys power; the rule of law, which constrains how that power is used; and mechanisms of accountability that ensure governments serve their people rather than themselves. Understanding how these elements interact, compete, and sometimes undermine each other provides crucial insights for anyone seeking to comprehend why some societies thrive while others falter. This historical perspective offers valuable lessons not just for scholars and policymakers, but for any citizen concerned with the health of their political institutions and the future of ordered liberty.
Chapter 1: The Origins of State Power: Bureaucratic Foundations (1600-1800)
The emergence of modern state bureaucracies between 1600 and 1800 marked a revolutionary transformation in how human societies organized political power. Prior to this period, most European states were patrimonial in nature - rulers treated government as personal property, appointing family members and favorites to key positions regardless of competence. This began to change dramatically as military competition intensified, particularly after the devastating Thirty Years' War (1618-1648). Prussia offers perhaps the most striking example of this transformation. Frederick William, known as the Great Elector, began building a standing army after the Peace of Westphalia in 1648. To support this military, he needed consistent revenue, which required a more efficient administrative system. His grandson, Frederick William I, took this process further by establishing a General Directory to centralize administration and creating the first truly professional civil service in Europe. Unlike previous systems based on noble birth or personal connections, the Prussian bureaucracy increasingly selected officials based on education and merit. This innovation allowed Prussia to punch above its weight militarily despite limited resources and vulnerable geography. In France, a different model of state-building emerged under Louis XIV. His finance minister Jean-Baptiste Colbert systematized tax collection and developed economic policies that strengthened royal authority. The French intendant system extended central control into the provinces, though it never fully overcame the entrenched privileges of the nobility and regional parliaments. This incomplete centralization would later contribute to the fiscal crisis that triggered the French Revolution. China had pioneered bureaucratic governance much earlier, developing civil service examinations during the Han Dynasty (206 BCE-220 CE). By the time of the Qing Dynasty (1644-1912), China possessed a sophisticated administrative system that could govern a vast territory with remarkable uniformity. However, without the competitive pressures that drove European state-building, the Chinese bureaucracy gradually became more concerned with cultural orthodoxy than administrative effectiveness. The rise of bureaucratic states fundamentally altered the relationship between rulers and subjects. Professional officials created a distinction between public and private spheres that hadn't previously existed. Government began to be seen as an abstract entity with its own interests, separate from the person of the ruler. This conceptual shift laid the groundwork for later ideas about citizenship and constitutional government, though these would only emerge fully in the next century. This period demonstrates how institutional innovations often arise from practical necessities rather than abstract ideals. The modern bureaucratic state emerged not from enlightened philosophy but from the brutal pressures of interstate competition. States that failed to develop effective administrative systems, like Poland with its paralyzed noble assembly (the Sejm), were eventually partitioned by more efficiently organized neighbors. The lesson was clear: adapt administratively or perish - a pattern that would repeat throughout modern history.
Chapter 2: Nation Building and Identity Politics: Prussia vs. Southern Europe
The contrast between Prussia's successful nation-building and the struggles of southern European states like Italy and Greece reveals how profoundly different paths of national identity formation shaped modern Europe. Between 1800 and 1900, these regions followed divergent trajectories that continue to influence their political cultures today. Prussia built upon its administrative foundations to forge a powerful national identity. The humiliating defeat by Napoleon in 1806 triggered not just bureaucratic reforms but a cultural renaissance. Intellectuals like Johann Gottlieb Fichte delivered his famous "Addresses to the German Nation," arguing that Germans constituted a distinct people with a special cultural mission. The Prussian education system, reformed by Wilhelm von Humboldt, created standardized curricula that instilled national consciousness. When Otto von Bismarck engineered German unification between 1866 and 1871, he could build upon decades of cultural nation-building that had prepared the ground for political unity. Italy's path to nationhood proved far more challenging. When unification finally occurred in 1861, Count Camillo di Cavour famously remarked, "We have made Italy; now we must make Italians." The new kingdom united regions with vastly different histories, economies, and even languages. Northern Italy had experienced industrial development and liberal governance under Piedmont, while the South remained feudal and impoverished under Bourbon rule. Most Italians spoke regional dialects rather than standard Italian, and literacy rates in the South were below 20 percent. The new state imposed northern institutions on southern regions without addressing these fundamental disparities, creating resentments that persist to this day. Greece faced even greater obstacles after winning independence from the Ottoman Empire in 1830. The new state encompassed only a fraction of Greek-speaking territories, with many ethnic Greeks remaining under Ottoman rule. The "Great Idea" (Megali Idea) - the dream of uniting all Greeks in one state - dominated politics for a century, culminating in the catastrophic Greco-Turkish War of 1919-1922. Domestically, Greek politics became trapped in clientelistic patterns, with politicians distributing state resources to supporters rather than building effective institutions. Unlike Prussia, Greece democratized before developing a modern bureaucracy, allowing political parties to capture the state apparatus for patronage purposes. The timing of bureaucratization relative to democratization proved crucial. Prussia established a professional civil service before introducing democratic institutions, allowing bureaucratic norms to become entrenched. When Germany finally democratized after World War I, its administrative system remained relatively insulated from political interference. By contrast, Greece and Italy introduced mass suffrage before creating modern bureaucracies, making it difficult to establish administrative autonomy from political pressures. These divergent experiences shaped how citizens related to their states. Prussians developed what political scientists call a "high-trust society," where citizens generally expected officials to act in the public interest. Southern Europeans, experiencing the state primarily as a source of patronage, developed "low-trust societies" where citizens viewed government with suspicion and sought to protect themselves through family networks and clientelistic ties. These cultural patterns proved remarkably persistent, influencing governance quality even after formal institutions converged through European integration. The contrasting experiences of Prussia and southern Europe demonstrate that successful nation-building requires alignment between state capacity, national identity, and political institutions. When these elements develop in harmony, they reinforce each other; when they develop unevenly, they can undermine effective governance for generations.
Chapter 3: The Challenge of Accountability: Democracy's Uneven Path
The period from 1800 to 1950 witnessed democracy's global expansion, but this process unfolded in strikingly different ways across regions. While some countries developed stable democratic systems with effective accountability mechanisms, others experienced what political scientists call "illiberal democracy" - competitive elections without the institutional constraints that make democracy function effectively. The American experience illustrates both the promise and challenges of democratic development. After independence, the United States established constitutional checks and balances, but the early republic remained governed by a narrow elite. Andrew Jackson's election in 1828 marked a democratic breakthrough, expanding political participation. However, this "Jacksonian democracy" introduced the spoils system, where government jobs went to party supporters rather than qualified professionals. American politics became dominated by clientelistic machines that exchanged votes for patronage. Only gradually, through reforms like the Pendleton Act of 1883, did the United States develop a professional civil service insulated from political interference. Britain followed a different sequence. The British civil service was reformed in 1854 through the Northcote-Trevelyan Report, which established competitive examinations for government positions. This professionalization occurred before significant democratic expansion - the Second Reform Act extending voting rights came only in 1867. By the time Britain approached universal male suffrage after World War I, bureaucratic norms of professionalism and political neutrality were firmly established. This sequencing helped Britain avoid the extensive patronage systems that characterized American democracy. Latin American countries generally followed a third pattern, introducing democratic forms without effective constraints on executive power. After independence from Spain in the early 19th century, countries like Mexico and Argentina adopted constitutions modeled on the United States, but lacked the underlying social conditions and institutional traditions to make these systems work as intended. Elections became mechanisms for legitimizing caudillo rule rather than ensuring genuine accountability. As political scientist Guillermo O'Donnell observed, these countries developed "delegative democracy," where presidents ruled with few practical constraints once elected. The interwar period (1918-1939) revealed democracy's vulnerability when accountability mechanisms remained shallow. Germany's Weimar Republic established a democratic constitution after World War I, but lacked a supporting political culture. When economic crisis struck in 1929, Germans increasingly turned to parties hostile to democratic governance itself. Similarly, Spain's Second Republic (1931-1939) collapsed into civil war as polarization overwhelmed fragile democratic institutions. These failures demonstrated that formal democratic procedures alone cannot ensure stable governance without deeper institutional foundations. Japan's experience offers a fourth pattern. After the Meiji Restoration of 1868, Japan built a powerful state bureaucracy and industrialized rapidly, but political development remained limited. The Meiji Constitution of 1889 established a parliament (Diet) with restricted powers, while real authority remained with the emperor and oligarchs. Only after defeat in World War II did Japan develop genuine democratic accountability under the 1947 constitution, which established popular sovereignty and expanded civil liberties. These diverse experiences reveal that democratic accountability requires more than just elections. It depends on a complex ecosystem of institutions including independent courts, professional bureaucracies, free media, and vibrant civil society organizations. Countries that developed these supporting institutions alongside electoral mechanisms generally achieved more stable and effective democratic governance than those that adopted democratic forms without the underlying substance. This historical pattern helps explain why contemporary democratization efforts that focus narrowly on elections often produce disappointing results.
Chapter 4: Institutional Decay: How Strong States Weaken
Even the most impressive political institutions can deteriorate over time, a process scholars call "political decay." The period from 1950 to the present offers numerous examples of once-effective institutions that gradually lost their capacity to fulfill their intended functions. Understanding these patterns of decay provides crucial insights into the fragility of political order. The Soviet Union represents perhaps the most dramatic case of institutional collapse. By the 1970s, the Soviet system had developed severe dysfunctions despite its apparent stability. The Communist Party, originally a revolutionary organization, had become a sclerotic bureaucracy more concerned with preserving privileges than solving problems. Central planning, which had mobilized resources effectively during industrialization, proved increasingly unable to manage a complex modern economy. When Mikhail Gorbachev attempted reforms in the 1980s, he inadvertently triggered forces that led to the system's complete disintegration by 1991. The Soviet experience demonstrates how institutions can appear outwardly strong while internally hollowing out. Japan's bureaucracy offers a different example of institutional decline. During Japan's economic miracle (1950s-1980s), ministries like the Ministry of International Trade and Industry (MITI) were widely admired for their strategic guidance of the economy. However, as Japan's economy matured and globalized, these same institutions became obstacles to necessary adaptation. The bureaucracy that had once driven growth became captured by the industries it was supposed to regulate, a phenomenon economists call "regulatory capture." When Japan's asset bubble collapsed in the early 1990s, these institutional rigidities prevented effective response, contributing to decades of economic stagnation. The United States has experienced its own forms of institutional decay. American administrative capacity, built during the Progressive Era and New Deal, has eroded through what political scientist Francis Fukuyama calls "vetocracy" - the proliferation of veto points that make coherent policy-making increasingly difficult. Agencies that once functioned effectively, like the Forest Service, have become paralyzed by conflicting mandates and interest group litigation. Meanwhile, Congress has grown more polarized and less capable of basic functions like passing budgets on time. This institutional deterioration has occurred despite America's continuing economic and military power. Developing countries have experienced different patterns of decay. Nigeria, despite enormous oil wealth, has seen its public institutions corrupted through what scholars call "prebendalism" - the treatment of public offices as prebends (benefices) that can be appropriated for personal gain. Civil service positions became vehicles for extracting bribes rather than delivering services. Similar patterns emerged across much of sub-Saharan Africa, where initial post-independence institutions deteriorated as patrimonial politics reasserted itself over bureaucratic norms. Several common mechanisms drive institutional decay across these diverse cases. First, institutions often fail to adapt to changing circumstances, with procedures that once served public purposes hardening into rigid orthodoxies. Second, officials within institutions gradually prioritize their own interests over the organization's mission, a process economists call "principal-agent problems." Third, powerful external actors capture institutions to serve their particular interests rather than broader public purposes. Finally, the intellectual frameworks that originally justified institutions become outdated or discredited, undermining their legitimacy. The historical record suggests that institutional maintenance requires continuous renewal and adaptation. Institutions that appear most stable often harbor hidden vulnerabilities, while their very success can breed complacency that prevents necessary reforms. This pattern of decay and renewal appears across diverse political systems, suggesting that maintaining effective governance requires not just building strong institutions initially but continuously revitalizing them as conditions change.
Chapter 5: The Balance of Power: Successful Political Development Models
The late 20th and early 21st centuries have witnessed remarkable diversity in political development trajectories. Some societies have achieved what might be called "balanced" political development - combining effective states, rule of law, and democratic accountability in sustainable ways. Examining these success stories reveals important patterns about how these elements can reinforce rather than undermine each other. South Korea's transformation offers perhaps the most dramatic example of balanced development. In 1960, South Korea was impoverished and politically unstable following the Korean War. Under Park Chung-hee (1961-1979), the country built a capable developmental state that directed industrialization through close government-business coordination. While initially authoritarian, this state created the economic foundations for subsequent democratization. When massive protests erupted in 1987, South Korea transitioned to democracy without sacrificing state capacity. The new democratic system gradually developed effective accountability mechanisms, including an independent judiciary and vibrant civil society. By the early 21st century, South Korea had become not just economically prosperous but politically balanced, with democratic institutions that could remove corrupt presidents while maintaining policy continuity. Costa Rica represents a different path to balanced development. Unlike its Central American neighbors, Costa Rica abolished its military in 1949, redirecting resources toward education and healthcare. This decision removed the threat of military coups that destabilized much of Latin America. The country developed a competitive two-party system with regular peaceful transfers of power, while building state capacity in key sectors like electricity and telecommunications. Costa Rica's social democratic model produced both high human development indicators and democratic stability, demonstrating that balanced development doesn't require the authoritarian phase that characterized East Asian experiences. Botswana stands out in the African context for its exceptional governance. After independence in 1966, the country maintained both democratic institutions and effective state capacity under President Seretse Khama. When diamond resources were discovered, Botswana avoided the "resource curse" that afflicted many mineral-rich countries, instead using the revenues for public investment. The country combined traditional Tswana consultative practices with modern democratic institutions, creating a system with both cultural legitimacy and institutional effectiveness. While facing significant challenges including HIV/AIDS, Botswana maintained both political stability and economic growth over decades. Taiwan's development paralleled South Korea's in many ways. Under Kuomintang rule, Taiwan built a developmental state that directed export-oriented industrialization while maintaining political control. Land reform created a more egalitarian social structure that prevented the extreme inequality characterizing much of Latin America. When democratization came in the late 1980s, Taiwan managed the transition while preserving bureaucratic effectiveness. The country developed a vibrant civil society and competitive party system that could hold government accountable without undermining state capacity. Several common factors emerge from these diverse success stories. First, these countries established basic security and administrative capacity before attempting full democratization. Second, they developed institutions appropriate to their specific historical and cultural contexts rather than simply importing foreign models. Third, they maintained relatively egalitarian social structures that prevented elite capture of political institutions. Fourth, they benefited from leadership that prioritized national development over personal enrichment or narrow factional interests. Perhaps most importantly, these societies achieved a dynamic balance among competing political principles. They built states strong enough to implement policies effectively but constrained enough to prevent abuse of power. They established legal systems that provided predictability without excessive rigidity. And they developed accountability mechanisms that ensured responsiveness to citizens while maintaining policy coherence. This balance wasn't achieved through a single institutional design but through an evolutionary process of adaptation and learning. The diversity of these success stories suggests there is no single formula for political development. Different societies have found various institutional arrangements that work for their specific circumstances. What they share is not a particular set of institutions but a functional balance among the core components of political order.
Chapter 6: Modern Challenges: Technology, Inequality and Governance
The early 21st century presents unprecedented challenges to political order worldwide. Technological change, economic transformation, and environmental pressures are testing governance systems in ways that reveal both new vulnerabilities and potential paths forward. Understanding these challenges requires examining how traditional governance mechanisms are adapting to rapidly changing conditions. Digital technology has fundamentally altered how information flows through society, with profound implications for governance. Social media platforms have democratized communication, allowing citizens to bypass traditional gatekeepers and mobilize directly. The Arab Spring demonstrations of 2011 demonstrated this potential, as protesters used Facebook and Twitter to coordinate actions against authoritarian regimes. However, these same technologies have created new vulnerabilities. Authoritarian states like China have developed sophisticated digital surveillance systems that monitor citizens with unprecedented precision. Even in democracies, social media has sometimes undermined shared factual understanding, making consensus-building more difficult. The challenge for governance systems is harnessing technology's democratizing potential while mitigating its polarizing effects. Economic inequality has emerged as another critical challenge. Since the 1980s, wealth has become increasingly concentrated in many societies, creating political as well as economic imbalances. In the United States, growing economic inequality has coincided with increased political polarization and institutional dysfunction. When economic elites can translate wealth into disproportionate political influence, democratic accountability suffers. Similar patterns have emerged in other democracies, where financial interests often shape policy outcomes regardless of electoral results. This concentration of economic and political power threatens the balance that successful political orders require. Climate change represents perhaps the most fundamental governance challenge, requiring coordination across both time and space. Political institutions designed for shorter time horizons struggle to address problems whose consequences unfold over decades or centuries. Democratic systems, in particular, face difficulties when current voters must bear costs for benefits that will accrue primarily to future generations. Meanwhile, the global nature of climate change requires international cooperation among countries with vastly different interests and capabilities. The inadequacy of existing governance mechanisms for addressing this challenge has become increasingly apparent. Migration pressures have intensified as economic disparities, political instability, and environmental degradation drive population movements across borders. These flows challenge traditional conceptions of citizenship and sovereignty that underpin modern political orders. Developed democracies face tensions between humanitarian obligations and popular concerns about cultural and economic impacts. Meanwhile, receiving communities often lack the institutional capacity to integrate newcomers effectively. These pressures have fueled populist movements that sometimes threaten democratic norms and institutions themselves. The international order itself faces transformation as power shifts from West to East. China's rise as an economic and political power has created a more multipolar system with competing models of governance. China's combination of authoritarian politics with market economics presents an alternative development model that has attracted attention, particularly in parts of Africa and Asia. This competition of governance models occurs as traditional Western powers face internal challenges to their own democratic systems, creating uncertainty about future international norms and institutions. Despite these challenges, successful adaptation remains possible. Countries like Estonia have pioneered digital governance systems that enhance both efficiency and transparency. Denmark and other Nordic countries have maintained relatively egalitarian societies while adapting to globalization. International cooperation on issues like ozone depletion demonstrates that collective action problems can be solved with appropriate institutional designs. These examples suggest that while current challenges are formidable, they are not insurmountable. The most successful responses will likely combine institutional innovation with renewed civic engagement. New governance mechanisms must address cross-border challenges while remaining accountable to citizens. This requires not just technical solutions but rebuilding trust between citizens and institutions. The fundamental components of political order—effective states, rule-bound governance, and mechanisms of accountability—remain essential, but their specific forms must evolve to meet contemporary challenges.
Summary
The rise and fall of political order across different regions reveals a fundamental tension between state power, legal constraints, and democratic accountability. East Asia developed strong states but struggled to limit their power through law and democracy. Sub-Saharan Africa inherited weak states that couldn't provide basic services or maintain order. Latin America established formal democratic institutions but often failed to overcome entrenched inequality and clientelism. These divergent paths reflect not just colonial legacies but deeper historical patterns of state formation, nation-building, and social mobilization. The most successful developing countries have found ways to balance these competing imperatives. They build state capacity without allowing bureaucracies to become unaccountable. They establish legal frameworks that constrain arbitrary power while reflecting local values and traditions. They create national identities that transcend ethnic and religious divisions without suppressing diversity. And they develop accountability mechanisms that improve governance rather than undermining it. This balancing act is never perfectly achieved, but the countries that have managed it best - from Costa Rica to South Korea - demonstrate that effective, democratic governance is possible under widely varying conditions. The challenge for others is not simply copying institutional forms but adapting them to local circumstances while maintaining their essential functions. Political development is not a linear process with a single endpoint but a continuous struggle to maintain balance among competing forces and interests.
Best Quote
“In societies where incomes and educational levels are low, it is often far easier to get supporters to the polls based on a promise of an individual benefit rather than a broad programmatic agenda.” ― Francis Fukuyama, Political Order and Political Decay: From the Industrial Revolution to the Globalization of Democracy
Review Summary
Strengths: The review highlights the comprehensive nature of Fukuyama's work, noting its broad and informative survey across epochs and cultures. The author is praised for his clarity, organization, and insightful writing. The review also appreciates the detailed historical analysis spanning multiple countries and centuries. Weaknesses: Not explicitly mentioned. Overall Sentiment: Enthusiastic Key Takeaway: The review emphasizes the significance of Fukuyama's exploration into the evolution of political order, focusing on the development of modern states through three essential factors: a functioning bureaucracy, the rule of law, and accountability. The work is valued for its depth and clarity in examining political institutions from prehuman times to the 21st century.
Trending Books
Download PDF & EPUB
To save this Black List summary for later, download the free PDF and EPUB. You can print it out, or read offline at your convenience.

Political Order and Political Decay
By Francis Fukuyama