
Raw Deal
How the “Uber Economy” and Runaway Capitalism are Screwing American Workers
Categories
Business, Nonfiction, Economics, Politics
Content Type
Book
Binding
Hardcover
Year
2015
Publisher
St. Martin's Press
Language
English
ISBN13
9781250071583
File Download
PDF | EPUB
Raw Deal Plot Summary
Introduction
The digital revolution has fundamentally transformed how work is organized, compensated, and experienced in modern society. What was once marketed as a liberating new model offering flexibility, autonomy, and entrepreneurial opportunity has increasingly revealed itself as a sophisticated system for transferring economic risk from companies to individuals. This transformation represents not merely a change in business models but a profound restructuring of the social contract that has underpinned economic security for generations. At the heart of this shift lies a carefully constructed narrative about sharing, flexibility, and technological inevitability that obscures the deliberate policy choices and power dynamics shaping the platform economy. By examining how digital platforms exercise control while avoiding responsibility, how worker misclassification creates structural advantages for companies at the expense of individuals, and how technological tools enable new forms of surveillance and management, we can understand the true nature of this economic transformation. The analysis reveals not only the immediate consequences for workers but also the broader implications for economic inequality, social stability, and democratic governance in an increasingly fragmented labor market.
Chapter 1: The Rise of Precarious Work in the Digital Economy
The American workforce has undergone a profound transformation in recent decades, with traditional employment relationships increasingly giving way to contingent arrangements characterized by temporary contracts, unpredictable schedules, and limited protections. This shift represents the rise of what economists call the "1099 workforce" - named after the tax form used by independent contractors rather than the W-2 form used by traditional employees. This classification difference is far from merely administrative—it represents a seismic shift in economic risk from employers to workers, creating a new class of vulnerable workers across virtually all sectors of the economy. The numbers tell a stark story about this transformation. According to recent surveys, between 30-40% of American workers now participate in the contingent workforce in some capacity. This includes not only low-skilled service workers but also professionals in fields like law, healthcare, education, and technology. For some, this arrangement offers welcome flexibility and independence. For many others, it represents an involuntary departure from the security and benefits of traditional employment, forcing them to navigate an increasingly precarious economic landscape on their own. This transformation didn't happen by accident. Since the 1980s, companies have systematically restructured their operations to minimize labor costs and maximize flexibility. What began as outsourcing manufacturing jobs overseas has evolved into a comprehensive strategy of replacing full-time employees with contingent workers across all sectors of the economy. Major corporations now maintain a small core of permanent employees while relying on an expanding periphery of temporary workers, contractors, and freelancers to handle fluctuating demand, effectively transferring business risk to individual workers. The technology sector has been particularly aggressive in adopting this model. Major tech companies maintain surprisingly small core workforces while relying heavily on contractors for everything from coding to content moderation. At Google, for example, contractors now outnumber direct employees. These workers often sit alongside regular employees, doing similar work but without comparable pay, benefits, or job security. One contractor at a major tech firm described the experience as "having a front-row seat to a world of perks and security that you're not allowed to access." The psychological impact of this shift cannot be overstated. Precarious workers report higher levels of stress, anxiety, and depression compared to those in stable employment. The constant hustle for the next gig, unpredictable income, and lack of social support create conditions of chronic insecurity. As one freelancer put it: "I'm not living paycheck to paycheck. I'm living gig to gig, which is much worse because I never know when or if the next one is coming." This psychological burden represents a hidden cost of the gig economy that rarely appears in economic analyses but significantly affects quality of life and long-term wellbeing.
Chapter 2: Platform Companies' Deceptive 'Sharing Economy' Narrative
The "sharing economy" emerged with a compelling narrative: ordinary people could monetize their underutilized assets and skills while building community connections. Companies like Airbnb and Uber wrapped themselves in the language of sharing, trust, and microentrepreneurship. Their founders spoke passionately about empowering individuals and disrupting outdated economic models. This framing proved extraordinarily effective in generating public enthusiasm and attracting billions in venture capital, while obscuring the fundamental restructuring of economic relationships taking place beneath the surface. Upon closer examination, however, the sharing economy reveals itself as something quite different from its utopian rhetoric. Rather than facilitating genuine sharing, these platforms have created highly efficient marketplaces for the commercialization of everyday life. Activities that were once performed informally or as acts of reciprocity have been transformed into monetized transactions. The language of "sharing" obscures what is fundamentally a profit-driven business model designed to extract maximum value from workers while minimizing corporate obligations and responsibilities. The economic reality for most platform workers contradicts the narrative of empowerment and flexibility. Studies consistently show that the majority earn below minimum wage after accounting for expenses, equipment depreciation, and unpaid waiting time. A TaskRabbit worker might appear to earn $25 per hour for a specific task, but this figure doesn't account for the unpaid hours spent searching for gigs, traveling between jobs, or managing administrative tasks. Similarly, Uber drivers must cover their own vehicle costs, maintenance, insurance, and fuel, significantly reducing their effective hourly rate. One study found that after expenses, nearly a third of drivers actually lose money. Platform companies have engineered a remarkable sleight of hand: they've created working relationships that contain all the elements of traditional employment - monitoring, discipline, performance evaluation, and dependency - while legally classifying workers as independent contractors. This arrangement allows them to exercise tight control over how work is performed while avoiding the legal responsibilities of employers. Uber, for instance, can unilaterally change fare rates, deactivate drivers based on customer ratings, and dictate minute details of service provision, yet still claim its drivers are independent business owners operating their own businesses. The asymmetry of power in these relationships is stark. Platform companies collect vast amounts of data about workers' performance, using sophisticated algorithms to manage their behavior while providing minimal transparency in return. Workers have little visibility into how assignments are allocated, how their performance is evaluated, or why their earnings fluctuate. They must navigate complex systems designed to maximize their productivity while having no meaningful voice in setting the terms of their work or challenging decisions that affect their livelihoods. Far from creating a new class of microentrepreneurs, the platform economy has largely produced a digital version of day labor. Most participants are not building sustainable businesses but rather patching together income from multiple platforms to survive. The freedom and flexibility celebrated in company marketing materials often translates to unpredictable schedules, income volatility, and constant availability. As one platform worker observed: "The flexibility isn't about when I want to work, it's about being flexible enough to work whenever they need me."
Chapter 3: How Worker Misclassification Transfers Costs to Individuals and Society
The distinction between employees and independent contractors has become increasingly consequential as more workers find themselves outside traditional employment relationships. This classification determines access to labor protections, benefits eligibility, and tax treatment, with significant implications for both individual workers and broader economic systems. When companies classify workers as independent contractors rather than employees, they avoid approximately 30% in labor costs by not paying payroll taxes, workers' compensation, unemployment insurance, and benefits. These savings come not from genuine efficiency gains but from transferring costs to workers and society. The financial impact on misclassified workers is substantial and multifaceted. Independent contractors must pay both the employer and employee portions of payroll taxes, effectively increasing their tax burden by 7.65%. They receive no overtime pay regardless of hours worked, no minimum wage guarantees, and no reimbursement for work-related expenses. Perhaps most significantly, they lack access to unemployment insurance when work dries up and workers' compensation if injured on the job. This absence of basic protections creates profound financial vulnerability, particularly for workers in physically demanding or hazardous occupations. Beyond individual hardship, misclassification creates broader economic externalities that affect all of society. When workers lack health insurance through employment, many ultimately rely on subsidized coverage through public programs or emergency services when care cannot be postponed. Those experiencing income volatility may need food assistance or housing subsidies despite working full-time hours. These public costs effectively represent an indirect subsidy to business models built on contractor classification, transferring corporate responsibility to taxpayers while allowing companies to privatize the benefits of worker productivity. The competitive dynamics created by misclassification are particularly troubling. Companies that properly classify their workers as employees operate at a significant cost disadvantage compared to those that do not. This creates a race to the bottom where responsible employers face pressure to adopt similar practices or lose market share. Entire industries have transformed as companies seek classification advantages, with traditional taxi services, home cleaning companies, and delivery businesses struggling to compete against platform-based rivals whose cost structures benefit from avoiding employer obligations. Legal frameworks have struggled to address these issues effectively. Current classification systems rely on multifactor tests that examine the degree of control exercised by businesses, the integration of workers into company operations, and the economic independence of workers. These tests, developed for an industrial economy dominated by stable, long-term employment relationships, struggle to categorize work in platform-mediated arrangements where control may be algorithmic rather than direct and workers often serve multiple businesses simultaneously. The result is extensive litigation, regulatory uncertainty, and inconsistent protections for similarly situated workers. The consequences extend beyond economics to affect democratic governance itself. When a significant portion of the workforce lacks basic protections and experiences chronic insecurity, social cohesion frays and political polarization intensifies. Workers struggling with precarious arrangements have limited capacity to participate in civic life or make long-term investments in their communities. The erosion of stable employment thus threatens not just economic security but the foundations of democratic society.
Chapter 4: The Economic Consequences of Income Volatility and Benefit Gaps
The rise of precarious employment extends far beyond individual hardship, creating systemic vulnerabilities throughout the economy. When workers lack stable income, their consumption patterns become erratic and constrained. They postpone major purchases, limit discretionary spending, and focus on immediate necessities. This reduction in consumer demand creates a negative feedback loop that ultimately suppresses economic growth. As economist Nouriel Roubini notes, "rising inequality becomes a drag on demand and growth, as it distributes income from those who spend more—lower- and middle-income households—to those who save more—high net worth individuals and corporate firms." The financial fragility of contingent workers has profound implications for household stability. Without predictable income, families struggle to maintain consistent housing, healthcare, and education. This instability particularly affects children, who may experience frequent moves, school changes, and periods of material hardship. Research shows that such disruptions can have lasting effects on educational outcomes and future earning potential, potentially perpetuating intergenerational poverty cycles and limiting economic mobility for entire families across generations. Housing markets have become increasingly dysfunctional as income volatility makes it difficult for workers to qualify for mortgages or maintain stable rental housing. Traditional lending models assume steady income and long-term employment - assumptions that no longer match reality for millions of Americans. The result is declining homeownership rates among younger generations and increasing housing insecurity. In high-cost urban areas, even middle-income contingent workers may find themselves priced out of the housing market entirely, forced into long commutes or unstable living arrangements that further undermine their economic security. The erosion of employer-provided benefits has shifted enormous costs onto individual workers and public systems. When companies classify workers as independent contractors, they avoid contributing to Social Security, Medicare, unemployment insurance, and workers' compensation. These workers must either pay the full cost of these programs themselves (as in the case of self-employment taxes) or go without protection. Many ultimately rely on public assistance programs when they face illness, injury, or job loss, effectively transferring corporate labor costs to taxpayers and straining safety net programs designed for temporary rather than structural economic hardship. Perhaps most concerning is the emergence of what economists call a "two-tier economy," with dramatically different experiences for those at the top and bottom of the economic ladder. The top tier enjoys unprecedented wealth, security, and opportunity, while the bottom tier faces chronic insecurity despite working longer hours across multiple jobs. This divergence threatens the social cohesion and shared prosperity that once characterized the American economy and undermines the promise of economic mobility that has been central to American identity and social stability. The macroeconomic implications of these trends are troubling. As more income flows to capital rather than labor, and as workers face increasing insecurity, the economy becomes more vulnerable to recessions and financial crises. Without stable incomes and adequate safety nets, households have limited capacity to weather economic downturns. Their financial fragility can quickly cascade into broader economic contraction as consumption collapses during periods of stress, amplifying rather than dampening economic volatility.
Chapter 5: Technology's Role in Fragmenting Traditional Employment
Technology has always shaped labor markets, but the current wave of digital innovation is transforming work at an unprecedented pace and scale. Artificial intelligence, machine learning, and advanced robotics are rapidly expanding the range of tasks that can be automated. Unlike previous technological revolutions that primarily affected routine physical labor, these technologies increasingly encroach on cognitive tasks once thought to be uniquely human domains, fundamentally altering the relationship between technology and human labor across virtually all sectors of the economy. Digital platforms have created new mechanisms for fragmenting work into discrete tasks that can be distributed across a global labor pool. This "taskification" of work allows companies to precisely match labor supply with demand, paying only for the specific moments of productive activity. A worker might be hired for a 15-minute task rather than an eight-hour shift, eliminating employer responsibility for downtime. This extreme efficiency comes at the cost of income stability for workers, who must constantly hustle for their next micro-assignment while absorbing all the unpaid time spent searching for work, communicating with clients, or traveling between jobs. The quality of jobs has deteriorated even in sectors where technology has created new employment opportunities. Platform-mediated work typically lacks the career advancement pathways, skill development, and social connections that traditional employment provides. Workers perform isolated tasks without understanding how they fit into a larger process or developing the expertise that might lead to better opportunities. The result is a growing class of workers who cycle through similar low-paid gigs without building marketable skills or professional networks that could provide economic mobility or career progression. Technology has also intensified work by enabling constant monitoring and performance optimization. Warehouse workers have their movements tracked to eliminate inefficiencies, call center employees are evaluated on their tone of voice and script adherence, and delivery drivers follow algorithmically determined routes that maximize stops per hour. This surveillance creates psychological pressure that many workers describe as dehumanizing. As one warehouse worker put it: "The algorithm is my boss now, and it's a boss that never sleeps and never shows mercy." The human cost of this algorithmic management often goes unrecognized in discussions of technological efficiency. The impact of automation extends far beyond manufacturing. White-collar professions previously considered immune to technological displacement are now vulnerable. Legal research, medical diagnosis, financial analysis, and journalism are all being transformed by algorithms capable of processing vast amounts of information and producing results that rival or exceed human performance. An Oxford University study estimated that 47% of U.S. jobs are at high risk of automation within the next two decades, affecting workers across the skill and education spectrum and challenging assumptions about which types of work will remain viable in an increasingly automated economy. The benefits of technological productivity gains have been distributed highly unequally. While digital platforms have created enormous wealth for founders, investors, and shareholders, the workers who power these platforms have seen their economic position stagnate or decline. This divergence challenges the traditional assumption that technological progress naturally leads to broadly shared prosperity. Instead, we're witnessing what economists call a "decoupling" of productivity and wages, with an increasing share of economic output flowing to capital rather than labor, fundamentally altering the relationship between economic growth and worker wellbeing.
Chapter 6: Portable Benefits and Individual Security Accounts as Solutions
The challenges posed by the transformation of work demand a comprehensive policy response that acknowledges both the realities of technological change and the fundamental needs of workers. Rather than attempting to reverse technological progress or restore outdated employment models, reforms should focus on ensuring that workers can thrive within the emerging digital economy while maintaining essential protections. Portable benefits systems represent one promising approach to addressing the fundamental mismatch between modern work arrangements and traditional safety net structures. The core principle underlying portable benefits is straightforward: every business that benefits from a worker's labor should contribute to that worker's safety net, regardless of whether the relationship is structured as traditional employment or independent contracting. Under this system, businesses would pay a small additional amount beyond wages—either per hour worked or as a percentage of compensation—into accounts that fund various components of each worker's personal safety net. This approach makes the employee/contractor distinction largely irrelevant for benefit purposes, focusing instead on ensuring universal coverage regardless of work arrangement. Individual Security Accounts (ISAs) offer a practical implementation of this principle. These accounts would connect with existing social insurance programs while adding portable benefits for needs not currently addressed. Employers would contribute to Social Security, Medicare, unemployment insurance, and workers' compensation through the ISA, with contributions tracked by individual identification numbers. For benefits without existing public programs—such as paid sick leave, vacation, and health insurance—the ISA would accumulate funds that workers could use as needed. The system would be proportional, with each employer contributing based on the amount of work performed or compensation paid. For workers with multiple income sources—an increasingly common situation—the ISA structure offers particular advantages. Consider a worker who spends 20 hours weekly with one employer, contracts 10 hours through a platform like TaskRabbit, and drives for Uber. Under an ISA system, each business would contribute proportionally to the worker's safety net, resulting in comprehensive coverage despite the fragmented nature of their work. This addresses one of the fundamental challenges in the modern economy: maintaining continuous protection despite discontinuous employment relationships. The cost of implementing such a system is surprisingly modest. Analysis of Bureau of Labor Statistics data indicates that providing a comprehensive safety net for service workers would cost approximately $2.91 per hour, while sales and office workers would require about $5.37 per hour. These figures include Social Security, Medicare, unemployment insurance, workers' compensation, health insurance, and limited paid leave. The costs could be further reduced through targeted implementation, starting with the most essential protections and gradually expanding as the system proves its value. Several successful examples demonstrate the viability of this approach. The construction industry has long utilized multiemployer plans that provide comprehensive benefits to workers who move between different employers. These plans are typically established through collective bargaining agreements and are governed by boards with equal representation from employers and workers. The benefits offered can be substantial, including health care, pension benefits, unemployment coverage, disability insurance, and even training opportunities. This arrangement allows workers to maintain continuous coverage despite changing employers, addressing one of the fundamental challenges of the gig economy. By creating universal coverage regardless of employment classification, portable benefits would eliminate incentives for businesses to misclassify workers or fragment jobs to avoid benefit obligations. This would level the playing field between businesses while ensuring that all work—regardless of its form—contributes to economic security. The approach recognizes that in a modern economy characterized by frequent transitions and multiple income sources, the safety net must be attached to individuals rather than specific jobs or employers.
Chapter 7: Rebuilding Worker Protections for the Platform Economy
The transformation of work through digital platforms demands a comprehensive reconsideration of how we protect workers and distribute economic risks in the modern economy. This requires moving beyond incremental adjustments to existing frameworks toward a fundamental reimagining of labor protections that can function effectively in an increasingly fragmented and digitally mediated labor market. Such reforms must balance the genuine benefits of flexibility and innovation with the equally important goals of economic security and fair distribution of productivity gains. A crucial first step is modernizing labor classification systems to reflect contemporary work arrangements. The binary distinction between employees and independent contractors no longer adequately captures the complexity of modern working relationships. Several countries have introduced intermediate categories that extend basic protections to dependent contractors while preserving flexibility. Others have adopted universal standards that apply regardless of classification, ensuring that all workers receive fundamental protections like minimum wage guarantees and anti-discrimination protections regardless of their technical employment status. Digital platforms themselves could be redesigned to enhance worker agency and economic security. Currently, most platforms are optimized to serve the interests of consumers and companies while offering workers minimal transparency and control. Regulatory frameworks could require platforms to provide workers with greater visibility into how assignments are allocated, how their performance is evaluated, and how their earnings are calculated. Additionally, platforms could be required to involve workers in governance decisions that affect their livelihoods, creating more balanced power relationships within the digital economy. Tax systems need updating to address both the challenges faced by contingent workers and the advantages enjoyed by companies that rely heavily on non-employee labor. Self-employed workers currently face higher effective tax rates than traditional employees due to the structure of payroll taxes. Adjusting these structures could reduce the tax penalty for independent work. Simultaneously, companies that extensively use contingent workers could face payroll taxes or other assessments that fund safety net programs, eliminating the current financial incentive to misclassify workers and ensuring all businesses contribute fairly to social insurance systems. Education and training systems require fundamental reimagining to prepare workers for careers characterized by frequent transitions and continuous skill development. Traditional education models that assume a linear progression from education to career are increasingly obsolete. Instead, we need flexible, modular learning opportunities that allow workers to acquire new skills throughout their working lives. Public investment in such systems would help workers adapt to technological change rather than being displaced by it, while ensuring that the benefits of innovation are broadly shared rather than concentrated among those with specific technical skills. Finally, strengthening collective bargaining rights and exploring new models of worker representation could help rebalance power in the digital economy. Traditional unions face significant challenges organizing contingent workers, but innovative models are emerging. Worker-owned platforms, sectoral bargaining arrangements, and digital guilds all offer potential pathways for collective action in fragmented labor markets. Policy reforms could facilitate these new forms of organization while removing barriers to traditional unionization, ensuring workers have meaningful voice in shaping the terms of their work regardless of classification. The ultimate goal should be an economy where technological progress enhances human potential rather than undermining economic security. This requires recognizing that markets alone will not ensure that the benefits of innovation are broadly shared. Deliberate policy choices are necessary to shape technological development in ways that serve the common good rather than concentrating wealth and power. With thoughtful reforms, the digital economy could deliver on its promise of greater flexibility and opportunity while maintaining the economic security essential for individual and societal wellbeing.
Summary
The platform economy represents a profound restructuring of economic relationships that transfers risk from companies to individuals while maintaining unprecedented levels of control through algorithmic management. What has been marketed as liberation through flexibility and entrepreneurial opportunity has instead created a new class of precarious workers who shoulder the costs and risks of business while being denied the protections, benefits, and stability that characterized traditional employment. This transformation reflects not technological inevitability but deliberate policy choices that have allowed companies to exercise employer-like control while avoiding employer responsibilities. Addressing these challenges requires moving beyond the false dichotomy between flexibility and security toward systems that provide essential protections regardless of employment classification. Portable benefits, individual security accounts, and universal labor standards offer promising pathways for rebuilding worker protections in the digital age. By ensuring that all work contributes to economic security regardless of how it is classified, such reforms would eliminate incentives for misclassification while preserving the genuine benefits of flexible work arrangements. The goal must be an economy where technological innovation enhances human potential rather than undermining economic security—where the gains from increased productivity are shared broadly rather than concentrated among platform owners and investors.
Best Quote
“The Death of Trade Unionism, and toward the Birth of a Labor 3.0,” ― Steven Hill, Raw Deal: How the "Uber Economy" and Runaway Capitalism Are Screwing American Workers
Review Summary
Strengths: Hill's ability to connect economic policies with real-world worker implications is a major highlight. A comprehensive approach and depth of research bolster his arguments effectively. The book's illumination of the gig economy's darker aspects, such as lack of benefits and job security, is particularly impactful.\nWeaknesses: Occasionally, the portrayal of the gig economy is perceived as overly negative. Some readers feel there is insufficient acknowledgment of the benefits, like flexibility and autonomy, which these platforms can offer.\nOverall Sentiment: The book is generally well-received as a thought-provoking and essential read for those interested in modern labor market dynamics. It is commended for its thorough analysis and call to action regarding the gig economy's broader implications.\nKey Takeaway: "Raw Deal" emphasizes the need for policy reforms to protect workers' rights in the gig economy, urging stakeholders to consider more equitable solutions in the face of digital economic shifts.
Trending Books
Download PDF & EPUB
To save this Black List summary for later, download the free PDF and EPUB. You can print it out, or read offline at your convenience.

Raw Deal
By Steven Hill